全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17713篇 |
免费 | 60篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2800篇 |
工业经济 | 840篇 |
计划管理 | 2697篇 |
经济学 | 4022篇 |
综合类 | 485篇 |
运输经济 | 36篇 |
旅游经济 | 66篇 |
贸易经济 | 4697篇 |
农业经济 | 19篇 |
经济概况 | 1494篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 573篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 6篇 |
2023年 | 17篇 |
2022年 | 7篇 |
2021年 | 13篇 |
2020年 | 35篇 |
2019年 | 60篇 |
2018年 | 2357篇 |
2017年 | 2112篇 |
2016年 | 1247篇 |
2015年 | 124篇 |
2014年 | 145篇 |
2013年 | 217篇 |
2012年 | 486篇 |
2011年 | 1978篇 |
2010年 | 1867篇 |
2009年 | 1561篇 |
2008年 | 1584篇 |
2007年 | 1892篇 |
2006年 | 84篇 |
2005年 | 402篇 |
2004年 | 474篇 |
2003年 | 561篇 |
2002年 | 265篇 |
2001年 | 79篇 |
2000年 | 69篇 |
1999年 | 8篇 |
1998年 | 32篇 |
1997年 | 6篇 |
1996年 | 23篇 |
1995年 | 7篇 |
1994年 | 6篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 2篇 |
1990年 | 6篇 |
1989年 | 4篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1987年 | 3篇 |
1986年 | 14篇 |
1985年 | 8篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 3篇 |
1982年 | 2篇 |
1980年 | 1篇 |
1973年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
991.
The death of Canadian manufacturing plants: heterogeneous responses to changes in tariffs and real exchange rates 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
We examine simultaneously the effects of real-exchange-rate movements and tariff reductions on plant death in Canadian manufacturing
industries between 1979 and 1996. Consistent with the implications of recent international trade models with heterogeneous
firms, we find that the impact of exchange-rate movements and tariff cuts on exit is heterogeneous—particularly pronounced
among least efficient plants. Our results further reveal multi-dimensional heterogeneity that current models featuring one-dimensional
heterogeneity (efficiency differences among plants) cannot fully explain: exporters and foreign-owned plants have much lower
failure rates; however, their survival rates are more sensitive to changes in tariffs and real exchange rates. 相似文献
992.
Katja Zajc Kejžar 《Review of World Economics》2011,147(1):169-193
This paper examines the role of inward foreign direct investment (FDI) in firm selection processes in the Slovenian manufacturing sector in the 1994–2003 period. It adopts the firm dynamics framework that allows testing of selection effects directly by assessing the impact of foreign firms’ activity on the probability of exiting of local firms (crowding out). The results show that intra-industry productivity spillover effects offset only a minor part of the competition pressure which results from foreign firm entry, hence incumbent firms experience a drop in their survival probability upon a foreign firm’s entry within a particular industry. This result is driven by foreign firm entry of the greenfield type, as entry through the acquisition of existing firms has no significant effect. The strength of the crowding-out effect decreases with the incumbent firm’s export propensity. There is no significant evidence that inward FDI would stimulate the selection process through backward linkages in the upstream supplying industries, whereas foreign firms’ activity reduces the exit probability of downstream local customers (through forward linkages). 相似文献
993.
Joachim Wagner 《Review of World Economics》2011,147(2):217-247
This paper uses unique new data for German manufacturing enterprises from matched regular surveys and a special purpose survey
to investigate the causal effect of relocation of activities to a foreign country on firm performance. Compared to non-offshoring
firms, firms that relocated activities were larger and more productive, and had a higher share of exports in total sales.
These differences existed the year before some firms started to relocate, and this points to self-selection of “better” firms
into offshoring. To investigate the causal effects of offshoring, six different variants of a matching approach are used.
Contrary to what is often argued we find no evidence for a large negative causal effect of offshoring on employment in Germany. 相似文献
994.
The spatial effects of trade openness: a survey 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Marius Brülhart 《Review of World Economics》2011,147(1):59-83
This paper surveys the literature on the implications of trade liberalisation for intra-national economic geographies. Three results stand out. First, neither urban systems models nor new economic geography models imply a robust prediction for the impact of trade openness on spatial concentration. Whether trade promotes concentration or dispersion depends on subtle modelling choices among which it is impossible to adjudicate a priori. Second, empirical evidence mirrors the theoretical indeterminacy: a majority of cross-country studies find no significant effect of openness on urban concentration or regional inequality. Third, the available models predict that, other things equal, regions with inherently less costly access to foreign markets, such as border or port regions, stand to reap the largest gains from trade liberalisation. This prediction is confirmed by the available evidence. Whether trade liberalisation raises or lowers regional inequality therefore depends on each country’s specific geography. 相似文献
995.
Nelson C. Modeste 《The Review of Black Political Economy》2011,38(1):53-62
This paper provides fresh estimates of income and price elasticities of import demand in Guyana, Jamaica, and Trinidad and
Tobago using a bounds test for cointegration. In addition, the paper also provides estimates of the consumption, investment,
and exports elasticities of import demand. These latter elasticities were all found to be positive and statistically significant
with values ranging from 0.16 to 0.55 in the long-run. 相似文献
996.
SFAS 158 mandated balance sheet disclosure of the funded status of firms’ Defined Benefit Pension Plan using the Projected Benefit Obligation (PBO) to estimate the pension liability. SFAS 158 caused a market phenomenon because the use of the PBO engendered dramatically higher estimates of pension liability and hence the perception of risk. Our work focuses on two aspects of this change in pension accounting: first, how will industry firms change their accounting strategy in light of the new rules, and second, how will firms’ stock prices be affected by the new allegedly better estimate of pension liability? Our research suggests that firms’ accounting strategies changed in that they use higher discount rates to estimate pension liability which offset the dramatic impact of using the PBO. In addition, we find that high financial risk firms’ tendencies to use higher discount rates increase with the firms’ leverage and decrease with liquidity. To test the market reaction we utilize standard event study methodology to investigate the effects of SFAS 158 on stock returns. Our findings suggest that firms with high (low) financial risk earn negative (positive) abnormal returns on and around relevant event dates preceding the implementation of SFAS 158. 相似文献
997.
This paper examines the effects of the Economic and Monetary Union on demand for foreign reserves. The traditional theory
on demand for international reserves assigns a pivotal role to imports. However, in a currency union part of imports are settled
in the common currency, leaving no incentive for keeping foreign reserves. Moreover, the pooling of the demand for reserves
in the currency union and an increasing role of a currency as an international reserve currency may also influence, among
other things, the union demand for reserves. Based on estimated demand functions for reserves it is shown that the Economic
and Monetary Union has reduced the demand for reserves substantially. It is argued that an enlargement with new member countries
of the European Union will result in further savings of reserves. A simple calculation at the end of the paper illustrates
the welfare gain associated with the reduced need of reserves in the Economic and Monetary Union. 相似文献
998.
Jeffrey Frankel 《Open Economies Review》2011,22(1):1-16
By putting together a relatively large data set on bilateral remittances of emigrants, this paper is able to shed light on the important hypothesis of smoothing. The smoothing hypothesis is that remittances are countercyclical with respect to income in the worker’s country of origin (the recipient of the remittance), while procyclical with respect to income in the migrant’s host country (the sender of the remittance). The econometric results confirm the hypothesis. This affirmation of smoothing is important for two reasons. First, it suggests that remittances should be placed on the list of criteria for an optimum currency area. Second, it brings into doubt plans by governments in some developing countries to harness remittances for their own use, in that government spending in these countries generally fails the test of countercyclicality which remittances pass. 相似文献
999.
Katja Zajc Kejžar 《Open Economies Review》2011,22(2):271-291
This paper examines the impact of foreign firm entry on the industry consolidation process in a host country that operates
through mergers and exits of incumbent firms. Using a three-stage oligopolistic model, the paper shows that foreign direct
investment (FDI) may trigger consolidation via a merger since the approval of a domestic merger by the antitrust authority
is more likely in the case a foreign firm enters via FDI and a firm’s incentive for a domestic merger is greater and that,
in turn, the possibility to merge and become more efficient modifies the outcome of the game by making FDI compared to exports
less likely. 相似文献
1000.
We argue that competitive diffusion is a driver of the trend toward international investment agreements with stricter investment rules, namely defensive moves of developing countries concerned about foreign direct investment (FDI) diversion in favor of competing host countries. Accounting for spatial dependence in the formation of bilateral investment treaties and preferential trade agreements that contain investment provisions, we find that the increase in agreements with stricter provisions on investor-to-state dispute settlement and pre-establishment national treatment is a contagious process. Specifically, a developing country is more likely to sign an agreement with weak investment provisions if other developing countries that compete for FDI from the same developed country have previously signed agreements with similarly weak provisions. Conversely, contagion in agreements with strong provisions exclusively derives from agreements with strong provisions that other FDI-competing developing countries have previously signed with a specific developed source country of FDI. 相似文献