全文获取类型
收费全文 | 107篇 |
免费 | 2篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 12篇 |
工业经济 | 7篇 |
计划管理 | 32篇 |
经济学 | 23篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 27篇 |
农业经济 | 1篇 |
经济概况 | 4篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 3篇 |
2023年 | 3篇 |
2022年 | 5篇 |
2021年 | 4篇 |
2020年 | 4篇 |
2019年 | 5篇 |
2018年 | 4篇 |
2017年 | 12篇 |
2016年 | 2篇 |
2015年 | 1篇 |
2014年 | 2篇 |
2013年 | 5篇 |
2012年 | 4篇 |
2011年 | 10篇 |
2010年 | 4篇 |
2009年 | 4篇 |
2008年 | 3篇 |
2007年 | 5篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 1篇 |
2004年 | 2篇 |
2003年 | 1篇 |
2002年 | 1篇 |
2001年 | 1篇 |
2000年 | 2篇 |
1999年 | 1篇 |
1998年 | 2篇 |
1997年 | 1篇 |
1996年 | 2篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1993年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1979年 | 1篇 |
1961年 | 2篇 |
1960年 | 1篇 |
1959年 | 2篇 |
1956年 | 1篇 |
1955年 | 1篇 |
1954年 | 1篇 |
1953年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有109条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
21.
Gieure Clara del Mar Benavides-Espinosa Maria Ribeiro-Soriano Domingo 《The International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal》2023,19(1):453-453
International Entrepreneurship and Management Journal - 相似文献
22.
23.
Summary. In this note we show that if in the standard Rubinstein model both players are allowed to leave the negotiation after a rejection, in which case they obtain a payoff of zero, then there exist a continuum of subgame-perfect equilibrium outcomes, including some which involve significant delay. We also fully characterize the case in which, upon quitting, the players can take an outside option of positive value. Received: February 27, 1996; revised version: March 28, 1997 相似文献
24.
Isabel Feito-Ruiz Clara Cardone-Riportella Susana Menéndez-Requejo 《Applied economics》2016,48(42):4051-4065
The aim of this study was to analyse the determinants of reverse takeovers, examining the influence of target firm shareholders’ type in the agreement. We examine reverse takeovers implemented in the Alternative Investment Market between 1999 and 2012, paying special attention to the differences between family and non-family target firms, as well as the impact of the financial crisis.
We propose that family firms have a lower probability of accepting a reverse takeover (‘shell’ firm), to avoid both diluting the ownership structure (loss of control) and new shareholders entering their firm. Our main findings show that the higher the percentage of ownership held by family holders, the lower the probability of their being the target firm in a reverse takeover. This effect is maintained during the crisis period, in accordance with the expectation that family firms will have fewer financial constraints. 相似文献
25.
Recently, the seasonal characteristics of macroeconomic time series have drawn a lot of attention. It has been argued that the seasonal component of many macroeconomic time series constitutes a major part of the series measured as a proportion of the variance. In addition it has been found that the seasonal component of most macroeconomic time series is constant and best “explained” by seasonal dummies. Specifically it is often found that a Christmas boom is followed by a beginning of the year trough. Based on quarterly and monthly macroeconomic time series from a large number of countries this paper shows that many macroeconomic time series have seasonal components that are changing over time. Furthermore, the Christmas boom and especially the 1st quarter trough is not found nearly as often as one might expect. 相似文献
26.
Review of Industrial Organization - This paper analyzes the interaction between product market competition and family ties on the structure of CEO pay, in a panel of publicly listed family firms.... 相似文献
27.
Clara Ponsatí 《Journal of Public Economic Theory》2004,6(5):675-691
We study bilateral conflicts that affect the welfare of third parties, the stakeholders. The conflict takes the form of a war of attrition and intervention is modeled as the possibility that the stakeholder “aids” the agreement with transfers to the contenders. We characterize the optimal policy when the stakeholder limits its intervention to a unilateral commitment to compensate the contenders if the conflict is resolved, and show that if contenders must be treated equally after agreement, then the optimal policy cannot eliminate the delay in resolving the conflict, and intervention is only advisable when the stakes are high enough. Economic diplomacy is modeled as a three‐player game where the stakeholder is actively involved in the negotiation where transfers are discussed simultaneously with a settlement for the conflict. We prove that, provided that none of the parties involved is too impatient, diplomacy benefits the third party in all conflicts. 相似文献
28.
Informed and Strategic Order Flow in the Bond Markets 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
We study the role played by private and public information inthe process of price formation in the U.S. Treasury bond market.To guide our analysis, we develop a parsimonious model of speculativetrading in the presence of two realistic market frictions—informationheterogeneity and imperfect competition among informed traders—anda public signal. We test its equilibrium implications by analyzingthe response of two-year, five-year, and ten-year U.S. bondyields to order flow and real-time U.S. macroeconomic news.We find strong evidence of informational effects in the U.S.Treasury bond market: unanticipated order flow has a significantand permanent impact on daily bond yield changes during bothannouncement and nonannouncement days. Our analysis furthershows that, consistent with our stylized model, the contemporaneouscorrelation between order flow and yield changes is higher whenthe dispersion of beliefs among market participants is highand public announcements are noisy. 相似文献
29.
Claudia Giordano Fabrizio Alboni Clara Cicatiello Luca Falasconi 《International Journal of Consumer Studies》2019,43(2):199-209
Household food waste is considered to be the largest share of food waste along the food supply chain. Given that its recoverability is also more challenging compared to food waste in other stages of the chain, most studies on household food waste adopt a pre‐emptive approach by aiming to identify and address consumer beliefs, attitudes and actions that are linked to food waste. In scientific literature, household food waste has often been studied in relation to the habit of purchasing discounted food products (DFP). However, findings have been contradictory. Specifically, while some authors found that deal‐prone consumers are usually of lower income and therefore display a wiser and more attentive attitude towards grocery shopping, other authors reported that the purchase of discounted products was usually linked to compulsive shopping, hence resulting in higher food waste quantities at home. Due to these discrepant findings, a definitive answer on the impact of DFP on household food waste does not currently exist in the literature. This paper analyses the correlation between the purchase of DFP and weekly household food waste quantities. To do so, we examine (a) the results of a food waste diary experiment carried out on a representative sample of 385 households in Italy in February 2017, and (b) the results of a 23‐items Computer Assisted Web Interview survey administered to the same householders, in which shopping habits were investigated. Results revealed no evidence of either a positive or negative relationship between the purchase of DFP and household food waste quantities. Frequency of grocery shopping was the only variable found to have a significant impact on household food waste quantities. 相似文献
30.
Who gets the carrot and who gets the stick? Evidence of gender disparities in executive remuneration
Clara Kulich Grzegorz Trojanowski Michelle K. Ryan S. Alexander Haslam Luc D. R. Renneboog 《战略管理杂志》2011,32(3):301-321
This paper offers a new explanation of the gender pay gap in leadership positions by examining the relationship between managerial bonuses and company performance. Drawing on findings of gender studies, agency theory, and the leadership literature, we argue that the gender pay gap is a context‐specific phenomenon that results partly from the fact that company performance has a moderating impact on pay inequalities. Employing a matched sample of 192 female and male executive directors of U.K.‐listed firms, we corroborate the existence of the gender pay disparities in corporate boardrooms. In line with our theoretical predictions, we find that bonuses awarded to men are not only larger than those allocated to women, but also that managerial compensation of male executive directors is much more performance‐sensitive than that of female executives. The contribution of attributional and expectancy‐related dynamics to these patterns is highlighted in line with previous work on gender stereotypes and implicit leadership theories such as the romance of leadership. Gender differences in risk taking and confidence are also considered as potential explanations for the observed pay disparities. The implications of organizations' indifference to women's performance are examined in relation to issues surrounding the recognition and retention of female talent. Copyright © 2010 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 相似文献