全文获取类型
收费全文 | 25075篇 |
免费 | 51篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 4190篇 |
工业经济 | 1403篇 |
计划管理 | 4082篇 |
经济学 | 5558篇 |
综合类 | 571篇 |
运输经济 | 53篇 |
旅游经济 | 93篇 |
贸易经济 | 5954篇 |
农业经济 | 365篇 |
经济概况 | 2203篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 610篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 46篇 |
2021年 | 89篇 |
2020年 | 134篇 |
2019年 | 170篇 |
2018年 | 2450篇 |
2017年 | 2229篇 |
2016年 | 1456篇 |
2015年 | 266篇 |
2014年 | 329篇 |
2013年 | 978篇 |
2012年 | 749篇 |
2011年 | 2241篇 |
2010年 | 2070篇 |
2009年 | 1806篇 |
2008年 | 1759篇 |
2007年 | 2113篇 |
2006年 | 293篇 |
2005年 | 573篇 |
2004年 | 647篇 |
2003年 | 733篇 |
2002年 | 418篇 |
2001年 | 232篇 |
2000年 | 196篇 |
1999年 | 149篇 |
1998年 | 159篇 |
1997年 | 141篇 |
1996年 | 151篇 |
1995年 | 120篇 |
1994年 | 137篇 |
1993年 | 111篇 |
1992年 | 120篇 |
1991年 | 99篇 |
1990年 | 104篇 |
1989年 | 104篇 |
1988年 | 97篇 |
1987年 | 81篇 |
1986年 | 100篇 |
1985年 | 126篇 |
1984年 | 118篇 |
1983年 | 93篇 |
1982年 | 130篇 |
1981年 | 89篇 |
1980年 | 97篇 |
1979年 | 80篇 |
1978年 | 87篇 |
1977年 | 67篇 |
1976年 | 68篇 |
1975年 | 66篇 |
1974年 | 42篇 |
1973年 | 52篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
11.
Thomas D. Willett Aida Budiman Arthur Denzau Gab-Je Jo Cesar Ramos John Thomas 《The World Economy》2004,27(1):25-44
Various claims have been made about the causes of the Asian crisis and its spread. Here, we use data on the behaviour of capital flows during the crisis to test the strong forms of four such hypotheses, that portfolio investors and hedge funds played a dominant role in initiating and/or spreading the crisis; that moral hazard kept efficient markets from predicting the crisis; and, finally, the common lender hypothesis of Kaminsky and Reinhart. In the process we also test implications of the Calvo-Mendoza model of rational investor ignorance. All are falsified as monocausal explanations. For example, portfolio investments that could not have been subject to substantial moral hazard continued to flow into Asia until very shortly before the crisis. Likewise, banks were a much larger source of capital outflows during the crisis than were portfolio investors. While falsified in their strongest forms, several of these hypotheses in less strong forms should play a role in a more nuanced analysis. It is necessary to move past simple single-factor approaches in order to produce a more complete, synthetic explanation of this episode. 相似文献
12.
Alison Thomas 《Business Strategy and the Environment》2001,10(3):125-134
This paper examines the correlation between the excess stock market returns and the adoption of an environmental protocol by companies. The underlying hypothesis that I test is whether evidence of the adoption of environmental policy, prosecution by an environmental agency or the routinized training of staff in environmental protocols, which proxies for the willingness of managers to invest for the long term, is associated with superior economic returns to shareholders. I find that both the adoption of an environmental policy and prosecution for breach of environment standards have significant explanatory power in an analysis of excess returns. Copyright © 2001 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. and ERP Environment 相似文献
13.
Thomas W. Downs 《The Financial Review》1993,28(4):549-583
A negative relationship between corporate leverage and tax shields has been predicted because a large nondebt tax shield reduces the expected value of interest tax savings and lessens the advantage of debt financing. Previous studies, however, have provided inconclusive and contradictory evidence on whether nondebt tax shields crowd-out debt financing. The analysis herein relies on unique constructs of discounted depreciation tax shields and presents evidence that crowding-out does not occur. Furthermore, it is shown that contradictory inferences may result from analysis of annual tax depreciation deductions instead of discounted tax shields. The findings suggest that firms with substantial cash flow from depreciation exploit their higher debt capacity by maintaining a capital structure with significantly more debt than otherwise. 相似文献
14.
Previous empirical research indicates that corporate insiders tend to increase (decrease) their shareholdings before events that increase (decrease) firm value. More recent evidence suggests, however, that passage of the Insider Trading Sanctions Act of 1984 (ITSA) may have deterred this behavior. Our results indicate that before passage of the ITSA, insiders exploited their access to nonpublic information by selling shares before the announcement of equity issues. However, after passage of the ITSA insiders no longer displayed this behavior. We conclude the ITSA has a deterrent effect, which is more heavily concentrated on insiders at the highest level of the firm who are most visible to regulators and other market participants. 相似文献
15.
Cross‐listings of equities internationally are becoming more common. Using data for Europe and North America, previous studies reject the order flow diversion hypothesis, which states that international cross‐listings reduce home‐country trading volume. We test this hypothesis using data for equities cross‐listed in Singapore and Malaysia. We find that trading volume in Malaysia fell 42.9% when Singapore markets were closed for holidays. Furthermore, we show that trading volume in Malaysia did not increase following the implementation of regulations that ended the trading of Malaysian equities in Singapore in 1998. Hence, we reject the order flow diversion hypothesis. 相似文献
16.
Terry L. Esper Thomas D. Jensen Fernanda L. Turnipseed Scot Burton 《Journal of Business Logistics》2003,24(2):177-203
The Internet has increased the level of importance of the end‐consumer market to transportation carriers. In two between subject experiments, carrier disclosure on retail merchant websites is examined as a strategic differentiation strategy. Predictions are offered concerning effects of carrier disclosure strategies on product delivery‐related expectations, consumer attitudes, and intentions to purchase a product online. Results from Study 1 reveal significant differences between disclosure and nondisclosure of the carrier for numerous product delivery‐related variables, as well as many differences between the six carriers examined in this first study. Study 2 extends these findings by showing that providing consumers with a choice of carrier leads to increased levels of satisfaction with the online experience and greater willingness to buy, relative to nondisclosure and disclosure strategies. 相似文献
17.
This study attempts to infuse relationship marketing theory into the study of logistics outsourcing relationships. In particular, the study demonstrates that not all of the partnerships between customers and providers of third‐party logistics services are the same in terms of their level of development. The existence of distinct levels of partnership established previously in the logistics literature is partially supported and a relationship between level of partnership development and the customer perceptions of key relationship marketing elements and outcomes is established. While exploratory in nature, these findings suggest there are benefits for the increased costs of developing closer partnerships. 相似文献
18.
Andrew Clare Richard Priestley & Stephen Thomas 《Journal of Business Finance & Accounting》1997,24(5):645-655
We test the robustness of the APT to two alternative estimation procedures: the Fama and MacBeth (1973) two-step methodology; and the one-step procedure due to Burmeister and McElroy (1988). We find that the APT is indeed sensitive to the chosen estimator and assumptions about the factor structure of stock returns. We believe that our findings have implications for the estimation of asset pricing models in general. 相似文献
19.
Summary. We prove existence of a competitive equilibrium in a version of a Ramsey (one sector) model in which agents are heterogeneous
and gross investment is constrained to be non negative. We do so by converting the infinite-dimensional fixed point problem
stated in terms of prices and commodities into a finite-dimensional Negishi problem involving individual weights in a social
value function. This method allows us to obtain detailed results concerning the properties of competitive equilibria. Because
of the simplicity of the techniques utilized our approach is amenable to be adapted by practitioners in analogous problems
often studied in macroeconomics.
Received: September 13, 2001; revised version: December 9, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" We are grateful to Tapan Mitra for pointing out errors as well as making very valuable suggestions. Thanks are due
to Raouf Boucekkine and Jorge Duran for additional helpful discussions. We also thank an anonymous referee for his/her helpful
comments. The second author acknowledges the financial support of the Belgian Ministry of Scientific Research (Grant ARC 99/04-235
“Growth and incentive design”) and of the Belgian Federal Goverment (Grant PAI P5/10, “Equilibrium theory and optimization
for public policy and industry regulation”).
Correspondence to: C. Le Van 相似文献
20.
This paper focuses on the 1986 Amendments to the False Claims Act of 1863, which offers whistle-blowers financial rewards
for disclosing fraud committed against the U.S. government. This law provides an opportunity to examine underlying assumptions
about the morality of whistle-blowing and to consider the merits of increased reliance on whistle-blowing to protect the public
interest. The law seems open to a number of moral objections, most notably that it exerts a morally corrupting influence on
whistle-blowers. We answer these objections and argue that the law is not objectionable on these grounds. Since there are
no compelling moral objections to the law, it is appropriate and acceptable to judge the law in terms of its economic costs
and benefits. We assess the most salient of these and conclude that the benefits outweigh the costs. We suggest that a mechanism
similar to the Act should be considered for protecting stockholders’ interests in the private sector. We conclude by making
several proposals for improving the existing legislation.
The authors' names are listed in alphabetical order.
An earlier version of this paper was presented to the Society for Business Ethics August 2004. 相似文献