全文获取类型
收费全文 | 154篇 |
免费 | 4篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 25篇 |
工业经济 | 8篇 |
计划管理 | 26篇 |
经济学 | 23篇 |
综合类 | 1篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 65篇 |
农业经济 | 3篇 |
经济概况 | 4篇 |
出版年
2022年 | 1篇 |
2020年 | 1篇 |
2019年 | 5篇 |
2018年 | 10篇 |
2017年 | 5篇 |
2016年 | 3篇 |
2015年 | 5篇 |
2014年 | 5篇 |
2013年 | 21篇 |
2012年 | 12篇 |
2011年 | 9篇 |
2010年 | 6篇 |
2009年 | 9篇 |
2008年 | 11篇 |
2007年 | 2篇 |
2006年 | 5篇 |
2005年 | 7篇 |
2004年 | 7篇 |
2003年 | 6篇 |
2002年 | 2篇 |
2001年 | 4篇 |
1999年 | 1篇 |
1997年 | 4篇 |
1996年 | 1篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1991年 | 3篇 |
1987年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 2篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
1981年 | 2篇 |
1980年 | 1篇 |
1978年 | 1篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1976年 | 1篇 |
1975年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有158条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
61.
Is it possible to beat the market by mechanical trading rules based on historical and publicly known information? Such rules have long been used by investors and in this paper, we test the success rate of trades and profitability of the Open Range Breakout (ORB) strategy. An investor that trades on the ORB strategy seeks to identify large intraday price movements and trades only when the price moves beyond some predetermined threshold. We present an ORB strategy based on normally distributed returns to identify such days and find that our ORB trading strategy result in significantly higher returns than zero as well as an increased success rate in relation to a fair game. The characteristics of such an approach over conventional statistical tests is that it involves the joint distribution of low, high, open and close over a given time horizon. 相似文献
62.
Christoph Böhringer Henrike Koschel Ulf Moslener 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》2008,33(3):299-317
In order to achieve their climate policy targets EU member states apply various regulatory instruments. We investigate the
potential efficiency losses arising from the imposition of emission taxes on sectors that are covered by the EU Emissions
Trading Scheme (EU ETS). Our analysis indicates the possibility of substantial excess cost through overlapping regulation.
We show that unilateral emission taxes on sectors subject to the EU ETS are environmentally ineffective and increase overall
compliance cost of the EU ETS.
相似文献
63.
In Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy Joseph A. Schumpeter concluded that socialism would eventually displace capitalism in Western democracies. This would come
about as a result of the superior performance of capitalism. We extract six “stylized” propositions that are essential elements
of Schumpeter's prediction about the fate of capitalism. These propositions are confronted with the development of the Swedish
economy. The three main results of the analysis are:
(1) The evolution of the Swedish economy closely followed Schumpeter's predictions until about 1980: Large firms became increasingly
predominant in production and innovative activity, ownership of firms became more and more concentrated, individual entrepreneurship
waned in importance, the general public grew increasingly hostile towards capitalism, and by the late 1970s explicit proposals
for a gradual transfer of ownership of firms from private hands were launched.
(2) Design of tax and industrial policies fueled a development of the economy along the lines predicted by Schumpeter. In
general, the policies discouraged private wealth accumulation. In particular, the policies favored concentration of firms
and concentration of private ownership.
(3) The turning point away from the path to socialism coincides with real world developments that disclosed two major flaws
in Schumpeter's analysis. First, the ever more obvious failure of socialism in Eastern Europe went against Schumpeter's assertion
that socialism can work. Second, Schumpeter, who thought that modern technology would make the giant corporation increasingly
predominant, did not foresee the revival of entrepreneurship that took place in the Western countries around 1980. 相似文献
64.
65.
Jose Anita Piening Raphael Engelberger Ulf Schiller Bernard Sallin 《Controlling & Management》2008,52(5):352-352
Vorschau
Vorschau Unsere Themen im n?chsten Heft 相似文献66.
This paper examines the decision by a multinational corporation (MNC) to relocate its business unit and/or corporate HQ overseas. We argue that business unit HQs move overseas in response to changes in the internal configuration of their unit's activities and the demands of the product markets in which they operate, whereas corporate HQs move overseas in response to the demands of external stakeholders, in particular global financial markets and shareholders. Using data on 125 business unit HQs and 35 corporate HQs, we test and find support for these arguments. The research highlights important differences between corporate‐ and business‐level strategy, and it suggests ways in which the theory of the MNC needs to be reconsidered. Copyright © 2006 John Wiley & Sons, Ltd. 相似文献
67.
Eva Johanson 《Quality and Quantity》1987,21(1):59-69
There is a lack of good registration methods for complex longitudinal data. Cumulating longitudinal data into cross-sections, even repeated ones, in order to allow for statistical analysis means considerable distortion of data; if they interact with each other, this is not possible to observe directly and the time factor is not taken into account to its full value, if at all. In this context, music may be defined as a complicated development in the course of time. Music is usually represented by musical notation which, if not ideal, means that we already possess a high precision registration method for complicated temporal developments. Musical notation used for registration of other longitudinal variables than musical ones allows for a multitude of qualitative variables being taken into account simultaneously and a high precision regarding the time factor. It should be no more difficult to analyse statistically a longitudinal pattern than a surface pattern. 相似文献
68.
The multiplier effects resulting from an isolated increase in the level of public consumption within different public branches are investigated and the policy implications are discussed. The article begins with a theorethical analysis which shows why and in which ways these multipliers can be expected to differ between public branches. Thereafter, an empirical investigation is given, based on simulations with an econometric model of the Swedish economy. In this model the public activities are divided into 13 different public branches. The effects of an increase in public consumption on employment, imports and private consumption are found to differ considerably depending on which branch of the public sector is expanded. Some implications for short run stabilization policy are discussed. The article ends with a special analysis of the implications for a medium term planning problem: the trade off between private and public consumption growth. This analysis throws new light on the old topic "private or public consumption". In an economy with highly differentiated production in the public sector the trade-off is shown not to be unique. The sacrifice of private consumption growth corresponding to a given growth of public consumption expenditures will vary considerably according to the distribution of the public consumption growth within the different branches of the public sector. 相似文献
69.
Ulf von Kalckreuth 《Empirical Economics》2011,40(1):205-235
Understanding adjustment processes has become central in economics. Empirical analysis is fraught with the problem that the
target is usually unobserved. This article develops and simulates GMM methods for estimating dynamic adjustment models in
a panel data context with partially or entirely unobserved targets and endogenous, time-varying persistence. In this setup,
the standard first difference GMM procedure fails. Four estimation strategies are proposed. Two of them are based on quasi-differencing.
The third is characterised by a state-dependent filter, while the last is an adaptation of the GMM level estimator. 相似文献
70.
Bjarne Florentsen Ulf Nielsson Peter Raahauge Jesper Rangvid 《The Financial Review》2019,54(4):833-856
We analyze equity diversification of all retail investors in a country (Denmark). We find that underdiversification is pervasive. We calculate the nationwide aggregate loss due to underdiversification and express it in absolute and expected‐return terms. The aggregate loss is large. We find that investors with low education, low income, and low wealth are more likely to underdiversify. Despite better diversification, the larger fraction of the aggregate loss nevertheless adheres to the top of the income/wealth distribution. Finally, our results indicate that underdiversification arises because investors have limited information about the benefits of diversification. 相似文献