首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   256篇
  免费   6篇
财政金融   33篇
工业经济   14篇
计划管理   31篇
经济学   42篇
运输经济   2篇
旅游经济   5篇
贸易经济   78篇
农业经济   12篇
经济概况   44篇
邮电经济   1篇
  2023年   3篇
  2022年   2篇
  2021年   6篇
  2019年   3篇
  2018年   5篇
  2017年   10篇
  2016年   9篇
  2015年   6篇
  2014年   9篇
  2013年   23篇
  2012年   17篇
  2011年   14篇
  2010年   6篇
  2009年   14篇
  2008年   10篇
  2007年   12篇
  2006年   7篇
  2005年   6篇
  2004年   2篇
  2003年   4篇
  2002年   4篇
  2001年   5篇
  2000年   3篇
  1999年   5篇
  1998年   3篇
  1997年   2篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   4篇
  1994年   2篇
  1993年   3篇
  1991年   4篇
  1989年   2篇
  1987年   4篇
  1986年   2篇
  1985年   2篇
  1984年   2篇
  1983年   4篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   4篇
  1980年   6篇
  1979年   4篇
  1978年   2篇
  1976年   7篇
  1975年   2篇
  1974年   1篇
  1973年   3篇
  1968年   2篇
  1927年   1篇
  1926年   1篇
  1922年   1篇
排序方式: 共有262条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
201.
Credit derivatives and loan pricing   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
This paper examines the relation between the new markets for credit default swaps (CDS) and banks’ pricing of syndicated loans to US corporates. We find that changes in CDS spreads have a significantly positive coefficient and explain about 25% of subsequent monthly changes in aggregate loan spreads during 2000–2005. Moreover, when compared to traditional explanatory factors, they turn out to be the dominant determinant of loan spreads. In particular, they explain loan rates much better than same rated bonds. This suggests that CDS prices contain, beyond general credit risk, to a substantial extent information relevant for bank lending. We also find that, over time, new information from CDS markets is faster incorporated into loans, but information from other markets is not. Overall, our results indicate that the markets for CDS have gained an important role for banks.  相似文献   
202.
Almost all of the transition economies in Eastern Europe andthe former Soviet Union experienced a severe decline in theirnational saving rates. The saving collapse could be explainedby the elimination of involuntary saving, a feature of centralplanning, or by a change in equilibrium saving reflecting thenew economic-circumstances following the end of socialism. Thepredicted saving rates of market economies with the same fundamentalsas the transition economies before the transition are computedto test for the presence of involuntary saving. The resultsprovide some support for the hypothesis of consumption smoothing.Also considered is whether differences in the extent of liberalizationaffected saving rates in the cross section of transition economies.This is found to be the case: greater liberalization is associationwith lower saving with a one-year lag. To the extent that liberalizationis associated with future growth, this finding is consistentwith smoothing in the face of output evolving along J-curve.  相似文献   
203.
We analyze a bioeconomic model of a multiple-host disease problem involving wildlife and livestock. The social planner’s choices include targeted (i.e., infectious versus healthy) livestock harvests, non-targeted wildlife harvests, environmental habitat variables, and on-farm biosecurity to prevent cross-species contacts. The model is applied to bovine tuberculosis among Michigan white-tailed deer and cattle. We find optimal controls may target the livestock sector more stringently when the livestock sector exhibits low value relative to the wildlife sector. This is in contrast with the conventional wisdom on the issue that controls should primarily target wildlife species that serve as disease reservoirs.  相似文献   
204.
205.
206.
Over the last years, proposals for the implementation of capacity mechanisms in Germany have been published. However, some basic questions have not been answered yet: regarding the need for capacities, the functioning of the energy-only-market and the objective and type of a possible capacity mechanism. The actual need for capacities is an important input factor for capacity mechanisms and crucial to determine whether these are required. Currently, uncertainties prevail due to differing assumptions regarding the capacity credits of renewables and other capacities. Existing studies show highly diverse estimates for capacity needs after 2020. It is also unclear whether the energy-only-market can provide sufficient investment incentives. The current low prices cannot be interpreted as a sign for market failure. They represent overcapacities due to European integration and increasing renewable shares. The mid-term effects of increasing renewable shares on electricity prices still need to be analyzed in detail. At last, the objective of a capacity mechanism is not clear in the German context. This makes the selection of an adequate capacity mechanism and an effective market design more complicated. Furthermore, effects on the energy market need to be considered. Parameterization errors can be expensive. Also, capacity mechanisms do not necessarily guarantee higher investment security. As a consequence, the authors advise against the prompt introduction of a capacity mechanism, especially as the new EnWG guarantees the operation of system-relevant power plants until 2017. Instead, an incremental improvement of the energy-only market and in-depth analysis of the described questions seam necessary.  相似文献   
207.
Wolf  André 《Intereconomics》2022,57(4):260-266
Intereconomics - With its communication “Sustainable Carbon Cycles”, the European Commission has opened a new chapter in European climate policy. For the first time, natural and...  相似文献   
208.
In this article, we develop a model for predicting distress events among large banks. We show that a bailout possibility induces different behaviors among small and large banks, and the proposed failure prediction model for large banks is thus considerably different from that for small banks. Major bank-level fundamentals show opposite conjecture directions for large versus small banks. The Tier 1 capital ratio, which is under the scrutiny of regulators and investors, has almost no distress prediction power among large banks. However, banks rescued by governments tend to maintain a lower Tier 1 ratio. The cost of funding in large banks is negatively correlated with the probability of failure, reflecting the fact that lenders internalize the too-big-to-fail (TBTF) policy and demand a lower interest rate from TBTF banks.  相似文献   
209.
We describe new experimental productivity dispersion statistics, Dispersion Statistics on Productivity (DiSP), jointly produced by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) and the Census Bureau, that complement the official BLS industry-level productivity statistics. The BLS has a long history of producing industry-level productivity statistics, which represent the average establishment-level productivity within industries when appropriately weighted. These statistics cannot, however, tell us about the variation in productivity levels across establishments within those industries. Dispersion in productivity across businesses can provide information about the nature of competition and frictions within sectors and the sources of rising wage inequality across businesses. DiSP data show enormous differences in productivity across establishments within industries in the manufacturing sector. We find substantial variation in dispersion across industries, increasing dispersion from 1997 to 2016, and countercyclical total factor productivity dispersion. We hope DiSP will enable further research into understanding productivity differences across industries and establishments and over time.  相似文献   
210.
Investments in renewable energy were at US$211 billion in 2010 and developing economies overtook developed ones for the first time in terms of new financial investments in renewable energy. Photovoltaics for generation of electricity from sunlight has the highest growth rate among the competing forms of renewable energy and has now begun to achieve grid parity in some regions. If these trends of investments continue, solar energy will play a major economic role. We analyze these developments and assess the ensuing amounts of investment and employment for a range of sizes of the sector of solar energy. We find that by 2050 electricity from photovoltaics could cover up to 90% of total global energy demand, with a then global capital investment in our main scenario in photovoltaic manufacturing capacity at 500 billion US$211 billion in 2010 and developing economies overtook developed ones for the first time in terms of new financial investments in renewable energy. Photovoltaics for generation of electricity from sunlight has the highest growth rate among the competing forms of renewable energy and has now begun to achieve grid parity in some regions. If these trends of investments continue, solar energy will play a major economic role. We analyze these developments and assess the ensuing amounts of investment and employment for a range of sizes of the sector of solar energy. We find that by 2050 electricity from photovoltaics could cover up to 90% of total global energy demand, with a then global capital investment in our main scenario in photovoltaic manufacturing capacity at 500 billion US2010 by around 2030 and 1,500 billion by 2050. Employment in photovoltaic manufacturing is predicted to rise to 6 million by 2050. Sensitivity analysis with respect to the core parameters of assumptions is supplied.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号