全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1269篇 |
免费 | 36篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 256篇 |
工业经济 | 200篇 |
计划管理 | 229篇 |
经济学 | 256篇 |
综合类 | 15篇 |
运输经济 | 12篇 |
旅游经济 | 25篇 |
贸易经济 | 193篇 |
农业经济 | 38篇 |
经济概况 | 81篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 10篇 |
2021年 | 8篇 |
2020年 | 17篇 |
2019年 | 22篇 |
2018年 | 35篇 |
2017年 | 28篇 |
2016年 | 44篇 |
2015年 | 30篇 |
2014年 | 29篇 |
2013年 | 165篇 |
2012年 | 39篇 |
2011年 | 53篇 |
2010年 | 43篇 |
2009年 | 56篇 |
2008年 | 47篇 |
2007年 | 48篇 |
2006年 | 32篇 |
2005年 | 39篇 |
2004年 | 38篇 |
2003年 | 27篇 |
2002年 | 33篇 |
2001年 | 31篇 |
2000年 | 39篇 |
1999年 | 28篇 |
1998年 | 21篇 |
1997年 | 24篇 |
1996年 | 18篇 |
1995年 | 16篇 |
1994年 | 18篇 |
1993年 | 10篇 |
1992年 | 14篇 |
1991年 | 13篇 |
1990年 | 12篇 |
1989年 | 6篇 |
1988年 | 9篇 |
1987年 | 13篇 |
1986年 | 8篇 |
1985年 | 17篇 |
1984年 | 17篇 |
1983年 | 20篇 |
1982年 | 8篇 |
1981年 | 11篇 |
1980年 | 15篇 |
1979年 | 12篇 |
1978年 | 15篇 |
1977年 | 16篇 |
1976年 | 10篇 |
1975年 | 5篇 |
1974年 | 7篇 |
1973年 | 5篇 |
排序方式: 共有1305条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
32.
Aside from immigration, the only meaningful demographic lever available to policymakers attempting to moderate the rate of ageing is the birth rate. This article departs from previous analyses of pro‐natal policies by studying determinants of pro‐natal options ex ante, which represents an advantage for policymakers looking to craft policies with prior knowledge of whether or not a demographic policy will have a significant effect. Our multinomial regression model for a US sample involving college students shows that the preferred choice of pro‐natal incentive is dependent on gender, economic class, number of planned children and migrant status. We find that females are more likely than males to choose any pro‐natal incentive over no incentive. The highest odds for increasing planned number of children are for maternity leave and parental leave options. Respondents associating themselves with the poorest economic class are more likely to choose daycare or government grant as pro‐natal options. 相似文献
33.
34.
This work provides a test of competitive theories of wage determination by examining the wages of identical workers across industry classifications. The finding that a set of significant industry wage differentials exists would seem to contradict a purely competitive theory of wage determination. However, the apparent presence of unmeasured human capital that is correlated with industry status does provide one potential competitive explanation for the industry wage effects. Moreover, non-competitive explanations for the differences in industry wages, such as efficiency wage theory or institutional factors, appear to be inconsistent with the nature of the wage differentials. 相似文献
35.
36.
Anthony J. deLeon Sharmila C. Chatterjee 《Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science》2017,45(3):402-427
Increasingly, knowledgeable business-to-business (B2B) customers and evolving customer needs are leading to seismic shifts in vendor–client interactions. Across industries, sellers are changing their business models from a simple goods orientation to a hybrid goods–services model, placing greater emphasis on delivering complete customer solutions. In such an environment, companies must find ways to prioritize investments in resource development. The service-dominant (S-D) logic framework offers significant insights into this challenge; however, these effects have not been tested quantitatively. This study addresses that gap, examining the influence of various seller resources on buyer satisfaction. An empirical analysis of buying organizations that purchased and implemented business intelligence systems finds that “augmented” operant resources that the buyers ascribe to the software’s sellers—resources that go above and beyond expectations—are the most significant predictors of both successful technology assimilation and overall customer relationship quality. In particular, an augmented operant resource reflecting a seller’s ability to see value creation opportunities from the buyer’s perspective (value mindset) has up to three times the effect on relationship satisfaction as “core” operant resources such as product-specific expertise or basic interpersonal service skills. These results can help sellers prioritize resource investments. 相似文献
37.
We develop a model in which social pressure on a firm to behave well is jointly produced by a state regulator (EPA) and an NGO. The EPA and NGO differ in how they trade-off business versus environmental interests and also have access to different instruments in pursuit of their objectives. In particular, while the EPA will typically have the tools for detecting misbehaviour, the NGO can influence the intensity of social hostility directed towards those found to have misbehaved. EPA and NGO efforts may be strategic complements or substitutes, depending upon circumstances. We present a taxonomy of outcomes in the game between EPA and NGO in the spirit of Fudenberg and Tiroles’s (Am Econ Rev Pap Proc 74(2):361–366, 1984) classic taxonomy of business strategies. We also consider strategic delegation from NGO supporters to an NGO that has tastes over environmental and business interests different to their own. 相似文献
38.
Anthony G. Heyes 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》1996,10(1):81-98
Regulatory agencies are often legally obliged to use a cost-benefit rule in revising environmental standards to reflect improvements in pollution-control techniques, but have considerable discretion over the timing of such revision. How should the agency use this discretion? Longer lags tend to encourage more intense R&;D effort by the regulated industry itself whilst discouraging parallel effort by external developers. Optimal implementation lags are characterized. The analysis calls into question the conventional view that “footdragging” by agencies is necessarily evidence of incompetence or regulatory capture. More generally, whether or not subject to conscious manipulation by regulatory agencies, the delays routinely observed in implementation may enhance welfare. 相似文献
39.
40.
The Role of Multinational Firms in the Wage-Gap Debate 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
The observation of an increase in the ratio of skilled to unskilled wages in the high-income countries and in some cases in low/middle-income countries has led to considerable discussion and controversy as to its cause. Virtually none of the analyses have considered a role for multinational investment in explaining the wage-gap phenomenon. This paper adapts the authors' earlier work to consider what role multinationals might play in factor markets. It identifies circumstances under which investment liberalization is likely to raise the wage gap in both the skilled-labor abundant and the unskilled-labor abundant country. 相似文献