首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   8093篇
  免费   229篇
财政金融   1593篇
工业经济   814篇
计划管理   1377篇
经济学   1699篇
综合类   87篇
运输经济   46篇
旅游经济   128篇
贸易经济   1327篇
农业经济   395篇
经济概况   852篇
信息产业经济   1篇
邮电经济   3篇
  2021年   56篇
  2020年   100篇
  2019年   139篇
  2018年   186篇
  2017年   172篇
  2016年   203篇
  2015年   110篇
  2014年   182篇
  2013年   842篇
  2012年   249篇
  2011年   298篇
  2010年   236篇
  2009年   280篇
  2008年   234篇
  2007年   231篇
  2006年   190篇
  2005年   211篇
  2004年   183篇
  2003年   176篇
  2002年   166篇
  2001年   192篇
  2000年   195篇
  1999年   168篇
  1998年   145篇
  1997年   141篇
  1996年   137篇
  1995年   127篇
  1994年   114篇
  1993年   123篇
  1992年   132篇
  1991年   117篇
  1990年   118篇
  1989年   108篇
  1988年   119篇
  1987年   101篇
  1986年   114篇
  1985年   130篇
  1984年   126篇
  1983年   123篇
  1982年   116篇
  1981年   112篇
  1980年   119篇
  1979年   92篇
  1978年   118篇
  1977年   89篇
  1976年   78篇
  1975年   61篇
  1974年   57篇
  1973年   55篇
  1972年   45篇
排序方式: 共有8322条查询结果,搜索用时 343 毫秒
51.
The Dynamics of Alliance Conditions in the Alliance Development Process   总被引:10,自引:0,他引:10  
One of the key issues in understanding the developmental processes of strategic alliances is how the alliance conditions change over the different stages of alliance development. A related question concerns the nature of the co-evolutionary dynamics of alliances in terms of their constituent partner firms. In this article we propose an integrated process model of alliances that is based on alliance conditions, allianc developmental stages, and an alliance system comprising co-evolutionary elements. We suggest that alliance conditions, or the key characteristics of an alliance at any given moment, link the alliance environment (firm characteristics) and the alliance development process. We also explore how specific patterns of alliance conditions have differential impacts on the interactive elements of the alliance co-evolutionary system.  相似文献   
52.
53.
The use of transferable discharge permits as a water pollution control policy is rapidly increasing in the United States. Drawing on evidence from existing water quality trading programs, this paper provides a taxonomy of the forms that such markets take. Four main structures are identified: exchanges, bilateral negotiations, clearinghouses, and sole-source offsets. Each of these structures has its own strengths and weaknesses; none is optimal for all scenarios. Since market structure is largely determined by a program's rules, policy makers should be aware of the differences between these structures and the conditions under which each comes to be.  相似文献   
54.
Agricultural policy reform has been an important source of change in the Chinese agricultural sector. The reforms led to productivity growth and helped China to pursue its self-sufficiency goal especially in the grain sector. In order to analyze whether observable productivity growth stems from technologically induced components or from the market induced parts, a multi-input–multi-output model is derived by using an econometric distance function framework. A decomposition allows to distinguish allocative effects, scale effects, technological change, and technical efficiency change. Data on farms in Zhejiang from 1986 to 2000 are used to analyze the impact of policy reform.  相似文献   
55.
56.
Evaluating FOMC forecasts   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
Monetary policy outcomes have improved since the early 1980s. One factor contributing to the improvement is that Federal Reserve policymakers began reporting economic forecasts to Congress in 1979. These forecasts indicate what the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) members think will be the likely consequence of their policies. We evaluate the accuracy of the FOMC forecasts relative to private sector forecasts, the forecasts of the Research Staff at the Board of Governors, and a naïve alternative. We find that the FOMC output forecasts were better than the naïve model and at least as good as those of the private sector and the Fed staff. The FOMC inflation forecasts were more accurate than the private sector forecasts and the naïve model; for the period ending in 1996, however, they were not as accurate as Fed staff inflation forecasts.  相似文献   
57.
A common approach to the evaluation of the standard of living is based on a function of real income. In the United States this often takes the form of CPI-deflated mean household income. Material well-being is more appropriately evaluated using a consumption-based index. Using data from the Consumer Expenditure Surveys we find that real mean income provides an inaccurate representation of the level and trend of the standard of living relative to real per equivalent total expenditure in the postwar United States. The differences between real income and real total expenditure per household equivalent member are found at all levels of aggregation.  相似文献   
58.
Chief Executives from New Zealand's largest companies were surveyed to distinguish divesting and nondivesting companies, and to identify the relative importance of the factors and motives which led to the divestment of 208 business units in the period 1985 through 1990. The divesting companies were considerably larger and faster growing than nondivestors. The typical divestment was motivated by the need to convert unattractive assets into liquid form which could then be held to strengthen the balance sheet, or reinvested in either the core business or new areas.  相似文献   
59.
The underidentification of linear models with measurement error does not necessarily extend to panel data models, as has been shown by GAiliches and Hausman (1986). We discuss and extend some of their results for a simple case and address particular issues concerning identification and asymptotic variances.  相似文献   
60.
This paper compares the output and revenue effects in the rate-of-return regulated monopoly model. Both the ad valorem and the unit tax generally decrease the use of capital, and as such, reduce the output and raise the price. In addition, it is shown that Suits and Musgrave's conclusion of higher revenue of an ad valorem tax at a given output can apply to a regulated monopolist if the marginal product of labor under the ad valorem tax is greater than or equal to that under the unit tax. Similarly, their second conclusion, that for a given tax revenue an ad valorem tax has a larger output than a unit tax rate before the revenue-maximizing tax rate, can also apply to the regulated monopolist.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号