全文获取类型
收费全文 | 504篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 172篇 |
工业经济 | 27篇 |
计划管理 | 74篇 |
经济学 | 96篇 |
综合类 | 1篇 |
运输经济 | 3篇 |
旅游经济 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 94篇 |
农业经济 | 1篇 |
经济概况 | 26篇 |
邮电经济 | 8篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 4篇 |
2020年 | 6篇 |
2019年 | 10篇 |
2018年 | 15篇 |
2017年 | 9篇 |
2016年 | 9篇 |
2015年 | 8篇 |
2014年 | 16篇 |
2013年 | 32篇 |
2012年 | 16篇 |
2011年 | 7篇 |
2010年 | 13篇 |
2009年 | 11篇 |
2008年 | 16篇 |
2007年 | 16篇 |
2006年 | 11篇 |
2005年 | 11篇 |
2004年 | 11篇 |
2003年 | 15篇 |
2002年 | 16篇 |
2001年 | 5篇 |
2000年 | 10篇 |
1998年 | 12篇 |
1997年 | 14篇 |
1996年 | 9篇 |
1995年 | 12篇 |
1994年 | 6篇 |
1993年 | 10篇 |
1992年 | 9篇 |
1991年 | 12篇 |
1990年 | 13篇 |
1989年 | 9篇 |
1988年 | 7篇 |
1987年 | 6篇 |
1986年 | 9篇 |
1984年 | 9篇 |
1983年 | 11篇 |
1982年 | 4篇 |
1981年 | 8篇 |
1980年 | 13篇 |
1979年 | 6篇 |
1978年 | 4篇 |
1975年 | 3篇 |
1974年 | 5篇 |
1973年 | 3篇 |
1972年 | 5篇 |
1971年 | 5篇 |
1970年 | 6篇 |
1968年 | 5篇 |
1967年 | 3篇 |
排序方式: 共有504条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
61.
62.
Zusammenfassung Die Wasserwirtschaft stellt eines der letzten noch verbliebenen Infrastrukturmonopole dar. Ist die monopolistische Angebotsstruktur
in diesem Sektor alternativlos oder w?re auch hier mehr Wettbewerb m?glich? An welchen Stellen der Wertsch?pfungskette sind
staatliche Regulierungen unverzichtbar und wie sind sie gegebenenfalls auszugestalten, um wettbewerbliches Anbieterverhalten
zu erm?glichen?
Prof. Dr. Dieter Cassel, 69, ist Emeritus für Wirtschaftspolitik an der Mercator School of Management der Universit?t Duisburg-Essen;
Dr. Christian Rüttgers, 29, war dort wissenschaftlicher Mitarbeiter und ist seit 2008 als Referent bei der Niederrheinischen
Industrie- und Handelskammer Duisburg-Wesel-Kleve zu Duisburg besch?ftigt. 相似文献
63.
By setting up a number of special economic zones, i.e. clearly demarcated regions regulated by special commercial legislation, the Chinese leadership intended, after a period of economic isolation, to integrate China more closely into the international division of labour and to stimulate production by using foreign capital and technology. Have the special economic zones so far been able to live up to expectations? What are the prospects for the future? 相似文献
64.
Rajan Varadarajan Raji Srinivasan Gautham Gopal Vadakkepatt Manjit S. Yadav Paul A. Pavlou Sandeep Krishnamurthy Tom Krause 《Journal of Interactive Marketing》2010,24(2):96-110
During the past decade, a number of interactive technologies, including the Internet, have fundamentally transformed how retailers compete in the marketplace. In a similar vein, emerging interactive technologies can be expected to significantly alter the retailing landscape through their impact on retailing strategy and operations. Furthermore, it is conceivable that certain emerging interactive technologies will be perceived by some retailers as enablers (tools to more effectively compete in the marketplace) and by other retailers as disruptors of the present ways of doing business. Interactive technologies can either be generic, a technology that is readily available from an information technology (IT) vendor and is widely adopted by retailers, or proprietary. An interactive technology that is proprietary can enable a firm to generate economic rents from the innovation for an extended duration of time. Investing in a generic interactive technology, however, may be perceived as a cost of doing business for a retailer, and not a potential source of sustainable competitive advantage. However, a retailer's complementary resource endowments may enable the retailer to more effectively leverage a generic technology relative to its competitors and thereby achieve a sustainable competitive advantage. In this paper, we review the related literature, develop a process model delineating the mechanisms by which an interactive technology can affect and necessitate changes in retailers' strategies and identify directions for future research. 相似文献
65.
Dieter Senghaas 《Intereconomics》1975,10(9):286-290
This article is a rejoinder to Professor Marion Mushkat’s contribution “Pheripheric Capitalism?” which was published in INTERECONOMICS, No. 5, May 1975. 相似文献
66.
67.
This paper explores theoretically and empirically the medium- and long-run relation of the terms of trade (ratio of traded goods prices) and economic growth of a pair of countries—one of which experiences a major catch-up process towards the other. Two theoretical interdependencies between the terms of trade and economic growth are offered: the home-market effect and the productivity-shock effect. These two effects are tested against each other in a cointegration analysis on data for Japan and the US from 1971 until 1997. Income is cointegrated with the terms of trade. The relevant empirical channel is the home-market effect. However, financial-market effects appear also to be relevant. J. Japanese Int. Economies 21 (4) (2007) 470–488. 相似文献
68.
Alan Krause 《International Journal of Economic Theory》2007,3(2):113-129
This paper examines the incidence of capital taxation in a model in which the taxation of capital is clearly justifiable and using analytical techniques from the tax reform literature. The taxation of capital has long been a controversial issue, with much of the literature concluding that savings/capital-income should not be taxed. Recently, however, Blackorby and Brett have shown in a model with several desirable features that it can be optimal to tax capital, and they provide a simple yet compelling argument in favor of both savings taxation and capital-income taxation. We use the Blackorby–Brett model (i.e. a model in which the taxation of capital can be justified) to revisit the question of the incidence of capital taxation. We focus on the generational incidence of capital taxation; that is, the incidence on a young generation and an old generation. However, an interpretation in terms of the incidence on \"capital\" versus \"labor\" (as is traditional in the tax incidence literature) is also provided. 相似文献
69.
Matthias Schmitt Dieter Sadowski 《International Journal of Human Resource Management》2013,24(3):409-430
The existence of host-country and country-of-origin effects is analysed by using the concept of fiscal federalism as a theoretical analogy. It is argued that multinationals try to minimize the costs of centralization and decentralization associated with cross-national personnel policy. The higher the costs of decentralization, the more likely is the existence of country-of-origin effects. The opposite holds true for increasing costs of centralization. This is tested empirically by comparing the human resource management and industrial relations (HRM/IR) practices of US and British subsidiaries operating in Germany with those of native German firms. Based on 297 valid cases, it is shown that the existence of decentralization costs is associated with country-of-origin effects in various areas of personnel management, such as the use of variable compensation, employee ownership and initial vocational training. In contrast, in the field of industrial relations (co-determination, compliance with collective bargaining), there are strong pressures to adapt to local norms, leading to host-country effects. These results indicate that a rationalistic cost-minimization approach is well suited to explaining the patterns of host- and home-country effects in regard to the HRM/IR practices of multinational enterprises. 相似文献
70.
Florentin Krause Stephen J. DeCanio J. Andrew Hoerner Paul Baer 《Contemporary economic policy》2003,21(1):90-105
This article examines how an integrated least-cost implementation of the Kyoto Protocol in the United States would affect U.S. competitiveness and jobs. Drawing on previous work, the authors analyze integrated emission reduction strategies based on a $50/ton carbon tax (including border tax adjustments), a payroll tax cut, energy-productivity–oriented market reforms, and international flexibility mechanisms. This policy portfolios is compared to conventional approaches that omit market and fiscal reforms.
Input-output data are used to estimate the impact on export prices of goods and services produced in the United States. Similar data are used to translate changes in GDP and energy production into employment impacts in energy and nonenergy sectors. The costs of providing transitional assistance for workers in the coal industry are compared to the GDP benefits of a profitable Kyoto strategy.
The analysis shows that relative to purchasing international emission rights, productivity-raising domestic market, institutional, and fiscal reforms offer much broader advantages for tradE-exposed U.S. industries. Though allowance purchases alone increase export prices of U.S. manufactured goods and services, an integrated no-regrets strategy reduces export prices for the large majority of U.S. industries and limits the impact of climate protection policies on the few most energy-intensive basic materials industries to very small levels. Relative to the baseline, an integrated least-cost implementation of the Kyoto target increases economy-wide employment levels by several hundred thousand jobs in 2010. 相似文献
Input-output data are used to estimate the impact on export prices of goods and services produced in the United States. Similar data are used to translate changes in GDP and energy production into employment impacts in energy and nonenergy sectors. The costs of providing transitional assistance for workers in the coal industry are compared to the GDP benefits of a profitable Kyoto strategy.
The analysis shows that relative to purchasing international emission rights, productivity-raising domestic market, institutional, and fiscal reforms offer much broader advantages for tradE-exposed U.S. industries. Though allowance purchases alone increase export prices of U.S. manufactured goods and services, an integrated no-regrets strategy reduces export prices for the large majority of U.S. industries and limits the impact of climate protection policies on the few most energy-intensive basic materials industries to very small levels. Relative to the baseline, an integrated least-cost implementation of the Kyoto target increases economy-wide employment levels by several hundred thousand jobs in 2010. 相似文献