全文获取类型
收费全文 | 326篇 |
免费 | 2篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 25篇 |
工业经济 | 18篇 |
计划管理 | 57篇 |
经济学 | 114篇 |
综合类 | 1篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 67篇 |
农业经济 | 6篇 |
经济概况 | 36篇 |
邮电经济 | 1篇 |
出版年
2020年 | 3篇 |
2019年 | 4篇 |
2018年 | 3篇 |
2017年 | 4篇 |
2016年 | 9篇 |
2015年 | 9篇 |
2014年 | 11篇 |
2013年 | 16篇 |
2012年 | 17篇 |
2011年 | 16篇 |
2010年 | 14篇 |
2009年 | 12篇 |
2008年 | 14篇 |
2007年 | 9篇 |
2006年 | 8篇 |
2005年 | 9篇 |
2004年 | 5篇 |
2003年 | 4篇 |
2002年 | 7篇 |
2001年 | 5篇 |
2000年 | 8篇 |
1999年 | 6篇 |
1998年 | 7篇 |
1997年 | 4篇 |
1996年 | 5篇 |
1995年 | 7篇 |
1994年 | 6篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 11篇 |
1990年 | 9篇 |
1989年 | 4篇 |
1988年 | 2篇 |
1987年 | 8篇 |
1986年 | 3篇 |
1985年 | 7篇 |
1984年 | 7篇 |
1982年 | 3篇 |
1981年 | 3篇 |
1980年 | 2篇 |
1978年 | 4篇 |
1977年 | 2篇 |
1976年 | 4篇 |
1975年 | 4篇 |
1974年 | 3篇 |
1973年 | 3篇 |
1970年 | 2篇 |
1969年 | 2篇 |
1964年 | 2篇 |
1960年 | 2篇 |
排序方式: 共有328条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
81.
Diana R. Franz Ramesh P. Rao Niranjan Tripathy 《The Journal of Financial Research》1995,18(3):311-327
Microstructure theory contends that dealers' bid-ask spreads should vary intertemporally with changes in the asymmetric information component of the spread. Corporate theory suggests that stock repurchase announcements signal management's private information to the securities markets. An examination of dealers' spread behavior around firms' open market repurchases in the NASDAQ market reveals a decline in spreads adjusted for dealers' inventory-holding and order-processing costs. This decline is attributed to a reduction in informed trading risk associated with the open market repurchase announcements. 相似文献
82.
Die Zusammenhänge zwischen den Veränderungen der Nachfragestruktur und dem wirtschaftlichen Wachstum
Franz Redl 《Journal of Economics》1964,23(3-4):330-367
Ohne Zusammenfassung 相似文献
83.
84.
Franz Wirl 《Journal of Evolutionary Economics》1997,7(1):73-89
This paper considers low dimensional (more precisely, one state variable) dynamic optimisation problems of competitive agents. These individual decisions lead to a dynamic externality for the evolution of the system. However, the impact of an individual and competitive agent is negligible and thus each agent considers this evolution as exogenous data. This leads, assuming rational expectations (perfect foresight due to the deterministic set up), to motions in the three dimensional space of state, costate and externality. Considering the fact that such externalities are widespread, e.g., R&D in the literature on new growth theory, pollution in environmental economics, etc., the incorporation of such externalities due to competitive markets is important, yet this incorporation may alter the stability of the system. Indeed, complex policies such as stable limit cycles are sustainable in such a low-dimensional economy, even for a separable and strictly concave model. 相似文献
85.
Based on a sample of 1,084 European regions (EU15) from 1995 to 2004, we estimate the relationship between the average growth
rate of GDP per capita and the volatility of the growth rate allowing for spatial effects. The spatial lag and spatial error
models show that the regional per capita growth rate and volatility are significantly positively related on average. However,
the inclusion of country interaction terms reveals that the volatility impact is not uniform across countries. In particular,
the relationship between growth and volatility is significantly positive for the majority of countries but significantly negative
for three countries (namely Finland, Italy, and Ireland).
相似文献
Martin FalkEmail: |
86.
Adél Bosch Franz Ruch 《The South African journal of economics. Suid-afrikaanse tydskrif vir ekonomie》2013,81(4):491-516
This paper applies a factor‐augmented Markov‐switching model to the South African economy to provide an alternative classification of the business cycle and its turning points. In the principal components step, 123 variables are used to establish the aggregate cyclicality in all sectors of the economy with the number of factors chosen using a modified Bai and Ng method. By exploiting the rich nature of the dataset, we provide a model with well‐defined statistical properties that compares favourably with the South African Reserve Bank (SARB) dating points. Combining the results of the parametric approach followed in the Markov‐switching model and the non‐parametric approach followed by the SARB should allow for a robust turning point analysis. A Markov‐switching model of real gross domestic product is also estimated because this variable is commonly used in the literature and provides a benchmark for the factor models. 相似文献
87.
The perception is that formal representation is increasingly common in UK Employment Tribunals (ETs), as case volumes and complexity increase. We investigate the nature of representation in UK ETs using the 2003 and 2008 Survey of Employment Tribunal Applications (SETA). The results suggest that between 2003 and 2008, the extent of formal claimant representation declined. The majority of employers and claimants are either heavily represented or have little/no representation, and there is little evidence that claimant representation is a response to employer representation at least at the level of individual claims. Overall, however, it would seem that some of the ‘accessible, informal and inexpensive’ characteristics envisaged by Donovan continue to apply only to cases within certain jurisdictions. 相似文献
88.
Nils D. Kraiczy Andreas Hack Franz W. Kellermanns 《Journal of Product Innovation Management》2015,32(3):334-348
Investigating the new product portfolio innovativeness of family firms connects two important topics that have recently received considerable attention in innovation and family firm research. First, new product portfolio innovativeness has been identified as a critical determinant of firm performance. Second, research on family firms has focused on the questions of if and why family firms are more or less innovative than other organizational forms. Research investigating the innovativeness of family firms has often applied a risk‐oriented perspective by identifying socioemotional wealth (SEW) as the main reference that determines firm behavior. Thus, prior research has mainly focused on the organizational context to predict innovation‐related family firm behavior and neglected the impact of preferences and the behavior of the chief executive officer (CEO), which have both been shown to affect firm outcomes. Hence, this study aims to extend the previous research by introducing the CEO's disposition to organizational context variables to explain the new product portfolio innovativeness of small and medium‐sized family firms. Specifically, this study explores how the organizational context (i.e., ownership by top management team [TMT] family members and generation in charge of the family firm) of family firms interacts with CEO risk‐taking propensity to affect new product portfolio innovativeness. Using a sample of 114 German CEOs of small and medium‐sized family firms operating in manufacturing industries, the results show that CEO risk‐taking propensity has a positive effect on new product portfolio innovativeness. Moreover, the analyses show that the organizational context of family firms impacts the relationship between CEO risk‐taking propensity and new product portfolio innovativeness. Specifically, the relationship between CEO risk‐taking propensity and new product portfolio innovativeness is weaker if levels of ownership by TMT family members are high (high SEW). Additionally, the effect of CEO risk‐taking propensity on new product portfolio innovativeness is stronger in family firms at earlier generational stages (high SEW). This result suggests that if SEW is a strong reference, family firm‐specific characteristics can affect individual dispositions and, in turn, the behaviors of executives. Therefore, this study helps extend the knowledge on the determinants of new product portfolio innovativeness of family firms by considering an individual CEO preference and the organizational context variables of family firms simultaneously. 相似文献
89.
90.
Franz R. Hahn 《Economic Notes》2005,34(1):113-126
Recent studies provide new empirical evidence confirming that financial development is linked to economic growth in OECD countries. Using new dynamic panel regression techniques, these appraisals indicate that within the group of high‐income countries stock market size as a measure of financial advancement contributes significantly to overall economic activity. Applying the same advanced techniques, this paper questions this conclusion by showing that the findings of these studies seem to be not only not robust with respect to adding new observations but also likely to be plagued by a severe price bias which belittles the information content of the used financial indicator (stock market capitalization). We provide evidence that anticipative price effects (i.e. expectations of future growth, reflected in current stock prices) may be driving the statistical relationship between stock market activities and economic growth in high‐income countries to a much larger extent than recent analyses of the finance– growth link in OECD countries suggest . 相似文献