首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   158篇
  免费   3篇
财政金融   19篇
工业经济   9篇
计划管理   24篇
经济学   12篇
综合类   1篇
运输经济   3篇
旅游经济   9篇
贸易经济   60篇
农业经济   12篇
经济概况   11篇
邮电经济   1篇
  2020年   2篇
  2019年   5篇
  2018年   2篇
  2017年   5篇
  2016年   5篇
  2015年   1篇
  2014年   7篇
  2013年   22篇
  2012年   10篇
  2011年   5篇
  2010年   4篇
  2009年   3篇
  2008年   11篇
  2007年   6篇
  2006年   3篇
  2005年   3篇
  2004年   3篇
  2003年   3篇
  2001年   1篇
  2000年   2篇
  1999年   1篇
  1998年   1篇
  1997年   1篇
  1996年   3篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   2篇
  1993年   4篇
  1992年   2篇
  1990年   2篇
  1989年   2篇
  1988年   2篇
  1986年   2篇
  1985年   4篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   3篇
  1982年   3篇
  1981年   1篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   2篇
  1978年   2篇
  1977年   3篇
  1975年   1篇
  1974年   1篇
  1973年   2篇
  1972年   2篇
  1970年   2篇
  1967年   1篇
  1943年   1篇
  1940年   1篇
  1918年   1篇
排序方式: 共有161条查询结果,搜索用时 700 毫秒
111.
112.
Stochastic differential equations (SDE) are used as dynamical models for cross-sectional discrete time measurements (panel data). Thus causal effects are formulated on a fundamental infinitesimal time scale. Cumulated causal effects over the measurement interval can be expressed in terms of fundamental effects which are independent of the chosen sampling intervals (e.g. weekly, monthly, annually). The nonlinear continuous–discrete filter is the key tool in deriving a recursive sequence of time and measurement updates. Several approximation methods including the extended Kalman filter (EKF), higher order nonlinear filters (HNF), the local linearization filter (LLF), the unscented Kalman filter (UKF), the Gauss–Hermite filter (GHF) and generalizations (GGHF), as well as simulated filters (functional integral filter FIF) are compared.  相似文献   
113.
114.
115.
116.
117.
For the multivariate analysis of binary (or n-ary) dependent variables, common statistical analysis systems offer models with non-homogeneous error variance (LSN-models), and optionally transformations (??response functions??) of the relative frequencies, above all the logit function. Using the simplest possible example??two groups with a relative frequency in each??it is shown that significance tests based on transformed and non-transformed variables can yield substantially diverging results, and even an example of flagrantly inadequate behavior of logit as a response function in significance tests is presented. Dispensing with LSN models can remedy the latter problem; this recommendation is in line with other known objections against using LSN with binary dependents. Furthermore, an improved approximation for the variance of (any) response function makes tests based on transformed and non-transformed variables equivalent, so that problems of discrepant results depending on the response function used are completely removed. In the Appendix a sketch is given of a method to extend the approach to more general situations.  相似文献   
118.
Recently, some economists have come to view economic development as a process of ongoing structural change which has self-organisational features. What is required is evidence concerning the self-organisational character of economic development. In other words, is economic growth associated with growth in the complexity of its structure and with a parallel rise in organisational interdependence? An extended version of qualitative input-output analysis, termed Minimal Flow Analysis (MFA), is used in this paper to analyse the structural linkages and changes that have occurred in the Queensland economy over the last two decades. The MFA evidence confirms that there has been a steady increase in the complexity of the Queensland economy. Economic coordination has occurred, to an increasing extent, through market intermediation. From a self-organisational perspective, it is clear that the Queensland economy has followed a rapid and coherent developmental path, marked by the emergence of bonded structures in its core and increasing complexity on its periphery.  相似文献   
119.
This paper develops a general approach to analyzing the expansion path of preferences. A framework is introduced that looks for modelling risk aversion using a normed distance defined on a real vector space. In this approach the distance between any two indifference curves is unambiguously measured by the absolute difference of a function depending on the utility. This forms a natural basis for analyzing the special case of an ? p norm. Furthermore, a link is made to the limit case of p = ?? allowing to encompass as a special case CARA preferences. Finally, some notion of normed equivalent is proposed and duality results are established.  相似文献   
120.
Zusammenfassung Der vorliegende Beitrag zeigt, daß es auch in der BRD etliche empirische Indizien gibt, welche für die aus den USA bakannte These «die Armen zahlen mehr» sprechen. Nach einer kurzen Erläuterung dieser These sowie der sie stützenden Einzelhypothesen und der Erörterung der dafür sprechenden empirischen Indizien in der BRD, wird schließlich die Frage aufgeworfen, ob die Verbraucherpolitik in der BRD nicht stärker auf die besonderen Probleme sozial schwacher Konsumenten ausgerichtet werden soll, um damit zugleich in Übereinstimmung mit sozialpolitischen Zielsetzungen deren Lebenslage zu verbessern.
The poor pay more — an ignored problem of consumer policy in the Federal Republic of Germany
The aim of this article is to focus the attention of consumer research and consumer policy in West Germany on the special disadvantages of low-income consumers. These disadvantages are well known in U. S. consumer and poverty research since the pioneering study in this field by Caplovitz (The Poor Pay More) but seem to be still largely ignored in West Germany.Surveying the available empirical knowledge on income differences and consumer behaviour in West Germany, four main factors can be identified which cause low-income consumers to pay more for the same goods (T1), or to get goods of lower quality, i.e., less value for the same amount of money (T2), than better-off middle-class consumers do.Firstly, in West Germany as in other western countries, low-income consumers, especially low-educated consumers, seem to be less informed than better educated middle-class consumers about market conditions, shopping opportunities, prices, and quality of goods. So they may have a greater risk of uneconomical buying. Remarkably, low-income consumers do not utilize the consumer's advice bureau or consumer information offered by the Stiftung Warentest to the extent that middle-class consumers do.Secondly, low-income consumers more frequently than middle-class consumers shop for food and daily necessities in small stores in their neighbourhood, more often buying in small quantities. Shopping in this way, goods are more expensive than by buying larger quantities in supermarkets or discount-stores. Interviews with low-income consumers in Munich (Studiengruppe für Sozialforschung, 1974) showed that this particular shopping behaviour is not mainly due to the lack of market information or to a preference by low-income consumers for personal contacts at shopping, as is sometimes maintained, but rather stems from budget restrictions which prevent large-scale buying, and from transportation problems facing low-income consumers without an automobile, especially in urban low-income areas and in rural settlements without discount-stores or the like.Thirdly, there is some evidence to suggest that low-income consumers in West Germany more frequently buy on instalment credit, which is supposed to be more costly than cash-payments or banking credits preferred by middle-class consumers.Fourthly, there is some empirical evidence in West Germany that low-income consumers, mostly low-educated, in contrast to middle-class consumers largely lack consumer know-how and shopping sophistication. So it can be assumed that low-income consumers are more frequently caught in unplanned and unfavourable purchases by persuasion of salesmen or pedlars. Presumably they also, more often than middle-class consumers, abstarin from taking action when dissatisfied. It is worth nothing, though, that the latest empirical findings in West Germany do not support the widespread view that low-income consumers do less household planning and budgeting and therefore more frequently do uneconomical shopping than middle-class consumers. Indeed, in the incidence of household planning in the country there seems to be no significant differences by income level. As strict household planning in West Germany is generally rare, in this respect one may only presume that many poor consumers pay more than would be necessary by careful income spending (T3).Referring to these findings, the recommendation is made that public consumer policy in the Federal Republic of Germany to an increasing extent should face up to the disadvantages of low-income consumers and attempt to contribute to the reduction of real-income poverty. As scientific knowledge on this issue is still very sparse in West Germany, the article closes with a demand for further research in the field.


Hermann Scherl ist wissenschaftlicher Assistent am Institut für Staats-und Versicherungswissenschaft der Universität Erlangen-Nürnberg (D — 8520 Erlangen, Kochstraße 4).  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号