全文获取类型
收费全文 | 20182篇 |
免费 | 454篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3937篇 |
工业经济 | 1687篇 |
计划管理 | 3142篇 |
经济学 | 4331篇 |
综合类 | 272篇 |
运输经济 | 157篇 |
旅游经济 | 304篇 |
贸易经济 | 3462篇 |
农业经济 | 926篇 |
经济概况 | 2333篇 |
信息产业经济 | 6篇 |
邮电经济 | 79篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 134篇 |
2020年 | 220篇 |
2019年 | 328篇 |
2018年 | 396篇 |
2017年 | 422篇 |
2016年 | 378篇 |
2015年 | 286篇 |
2014年 | 431篇 |
2013年 | 2032篇 |
2012年 | 556篇 |
2011年 | 646篇 |
2010年 | 585篇 |
2009年 | 676篇 |
2008年 | 612篇 |
2007年 | 518篇 |
2006年 | 487篇 |
2005年 | 546篇 |
2004年 | 448篇 |
2003年 | 486篇 |
2002年 | 426篇 |
2001年 | 427篇 |
2000年 | 398篇 |
1999年 | 399篇 |
1998年 | 361篇 |
1997年 | 376篇 |
1996年 | 374篇 |
1995年 | 339篇 |
1994年 | 348篇 |
1993年 | 298篇 |
1992年 | 312篇 |
1991年 | 315篇 |
1990年 | 260篇 |
1989年 | 234篇 |
1988年 | 229篇 |
1987年 | 198篇 |
1986年 | 251篇 |
1985年 | 353篇 |
1984年 | 331篇 |
1983年 | 321篇 |
1982年 | 297篇 |
1981年 | 290篇 |
1980年 | 265篇 |
1979年 | 275篇 |
1978年 | 239篇 |
1977年 | 219篇 |
1976年 | 190篇 |
1975年 | 153篇 |
1974年 | 160篇 |
1973年 | 121篇 |
1972年 | 121篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
21.
22.
Thomas W. Downs 《The Financial Review》1993,28(4):549-583
A negative relationship between corporate leverage and tax shields has been predicted because a large nondebt tax shield reduces the expected value of interest tax savings and lessens the advantage of debt financing. Previous studies, however, have provided inconclusive and contradictory evidence on whether nondebt tax shields crowd-out debt financing. The analysis herein relies on unique constructs of discounted depreciation tax shields and presents evidence that crowding-out does not occur. Furthermore, it is shown that contradictory inferences may result from analysis of annual tax depreciation deductions instead of discounted tax shields. The findings suggest that firms with substantial cash flow from depreciation exploit their higher debt capacity by maintaining a capital structure with significantly more debt than otherwise. 相似文献
23.
24.
25.
Abstract. This research identifies those characteristics that could potentially influence a choice to create an internal audit department and tests via discriminant analysis to evaluate whether such attributes significantly distinguish between companies with and without an internal audit department. In addition, qualitative characteristics of such departments are described, as is the association of such traits with errors and the overall control environment. A sample of 260 companies is examined. Companies with internal audit departments are observed to be significantly larger, more highly regulated, more competitive, more profitable, more liquid, more conservative in accounting policies, more competent in their management and accounting personnel, and subject to better management controls. Key discriminant variables are the degree of regulation, decentralization, size, the duration of association with present auditors, the existence of an audit committee, EDP control, and pressures by external parties on management to achieve budgetary goals. Qualitative attributes of internal audit are systematically associated with the overall quality of the control environment, as well as errors. The most important attribute appears to be the independence of internal audit in terms of the propriety of the reporting level. An advantage of internal auditing is that external auditors report a 10 percent reduction in the number of hours incurred and greater flexibility appears to exist in the proportion of work performed in off-peak periods. Résumé. Les auteurs dressent l'inventaire des caractéristiques susceptibles d'influer sur le choix de créer un service de vérification interne et soumettent ces attributs à des tests, par voie d'analyse discriminante, afin de déterminer s'ils permettent d'établir une distinction claire entre les entreprises ayant et n'ayant pas de service de vérification interne. De plus, ils décrivent les caractéristiques qualitatives de ces services, de même que l'association de ces carctéristiques aux erreurs et au contexte global du contrôle. Les auteurs procèdent à l'examen d'un échantillon de 260 entreprises. L'étude révèle que les entreprises possédant des services de vérification interne sont beaucoup plus souvent des entreprises de grande taille, faisant l'objet d'une réglementation plus rigoureuse, plus concurrentielles, plus rentables, ayant davantage de liquidités, plus prudentes dans leurs conventions compatables, possédant une équipe de gestion et un personnel comptable plus compétents et soumises à de meilleurs contrôles de gestion. Les principales variables discriminantes sont le degré de réglementation, la décentralisation, la taille, la durée de l'association avec les vérificateurs actuels, l'existence d'un comité de vérification, le contrôle dans un cadre informatique et les pressions exercées par les tiers sur la direction pour l'atteinte des objectifs budgétaires. Les attributs qualitatifs de la vérification interne sont systématiquement asociés à la qualité globale du cadre de contrôle, de même qu'aux erreurs. L'attribut le plus important semble être le degré d'autonomie du service de vérification interne, c'est-à-dire le caractère approprié de ses liens hiérarchiques. La vérification interne comporte un avantage: les vérificateurs externes font état d'une réduction de 10 pour cent dans le nombre d'heures consacrées à la vérification, et il semble exister une plus grande souplesse dans la proportion du travail de vérification effectué en dehors des périodes de pointe. 相似文献
26.
This paper models the demand for stockbrokers' services in Australia, consisting of two related services, agency trades and principal trades. The relationship between agency and principal trades is estimated. The results indicate that the two services are complements rather than substitutes. Using unique accounting information, a model of agency and principal trading activities is estimated to determine the welfare effects of (i) deregulating brokerage commissions and (ii) a ban on principal trading by brokers. The results show a sizeable welfare gain to investors (amounting to about 60% of the gross revenue of brokers) stemming from deregulation of the minimum charge for agency trades. The loss in profitability by brokers due to deregulation is also computed and shown to be negligible. The results also show that due to complementarity, a ban on principal trading, even with deregulation of agency trading, can impose an arbitrarily high cost on investors which could, in principle, offset the gains from agency deregulation. 相似文献
27.
28.
29.
30.
Dynamic futures‐hedging ratios are estimated across seven markets using generalized models of the variance/covariance structure. The hedging performances of the resultant dynamic strategies are then compared with static and naïve strategies, both in‐ and out‐of‐sample. Bayesian‐adjusted hedge ratios also are employed as error purgers. The empirical results indicate that the generalized dynamic models are well specified and that their use in determining optimal hedge ratios can lead to improvements in hedging performance as measured by the volatilities of the returns on the optimally hedged position. © 2003 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 23:241–260, 2003 相似文献