全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17598篇 |
免费 | 104篇 |
国内免费 | 3篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2789篇 |
工业经济 | 1815篇 |
计划管理 | 3192篇 |
经济学 | 3858篇 |
综合类 | 315篇 |
运输经济 | 104篇 |
旅游经济 | 334篇 |
贸易经济 | 2855篇 |
农业经济 | 842篇 |
经济概况 | 1577篇 |
邮电经济 | 24篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 104篇 |
2020年 | 196篇 |
2019年 | 262篇 |
2018年 | 298篇 |
2017年 | 354篇 |
2016年 | 356篇 |
2015年 | 249篇 |
2014年 | 384篇 |
2013年 | 1523篇 |
2012年 | 496篇 |
2011年 | 778篇 |
2010年 | 686篇 |
2009年 | 645篇 |
2008年 | 641篇 |
2007年 | 609篇 |
2006年 | 514篇 |
2005年 | 466篇 |
2004年 | 401篇 |
2003年 | 409篇 |
2002年 | 395篇 |
2001年 | 327篇 |
2000年 | 331篇 |
1999年 | 311篇 |
1998年 | 310篇 |
1997年 | 305篇 |
1996年 | 309篇 |
1995年 | 274篇 |
1994年 | 259篇 |
1993年 | 273篇 |
1992年 | 269篇 |
1991年 | 258篇 |
1990年 | 242篇 |
1989年 | 211篇 |
1988年 | 170篇 |
1987年 | 199篇 |
1986年 | 204篇 |
1985年 | 299篇 |
1984年 | 296篇 |
1983年 | 306篇 |
1982年 | 263篇 |
1981年 | 251篇 |
1980年 | 208篇 |
1979年 | 227篇 |
1978年 | 169篇 |
1977年 | 174篇 |
1976年 | 151篇 |
1975年 | 115篇 |
1974年 | 116篇 |
1973年 | 107篇 |
1970年 | 71篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
991.
992.
Biersack KL 《Medical economics》1997,74(2):92, 95, 100 passim
993.
Michael L Wyzan 《Journal of Comparative Economics》1985,9(1):24-45
The relationship between Soviet agricultural procurement prices and quantities is examined in the light of the existence of bonuses for above-trend sales (BATS) and zonal price differentiation (ZPD). That BATS leads to a positive relationship between prices and quantities as harvest conditions vary is shown to hold for the individual farm. Planners are apt, however, to be more concerned with the “average” price of a crop, which is closely related to the subsidy bill. This price is more likely to be “perverse” under ZPD than BATS, although neither guarantees perversity. Data suggest that such perversity is a common occurrence. J. Comp. Econ., March 1985, 9(1), pp. 24–45. Illinois State University, Normal, Illinois 61761. 相似文献
994.
995.
Edgar L. Feige 《Economic Policy》2000,15(31):473-511
This paper examines the desirability and feasibility of replacing the present system of personal and corporate income, sales, excise, capital gains, import and export duties, gift and estate taxes with a single comprehensive revenue neutral Automated Payment Transaction (APT) tax. In its simplest form, the APT tax consists of a flat tax levied on all transactions. The tax is automatically assessed and collected when transactions are settled through the electronic technology of the banking/payments system. The APT tax introduces progressivity through the tax base since the volume of final payments includes exchanges of titles to property and is therefore more highly skewed than the conventional income or consumption tax base. The wealthy carry out a disproportionate share of total transactions and therefore bear a disproportionate burden of the tax despite its flat rate structure. The automated recording of all APT tax payments by firms and individuals eliminates the need to file tax and information returns and creates a degree of transparency and perceived fairness that induces greater tax compliance. Also, the tax has lower administrative and compliance cost. Like all taxes, the APT tax creates new distortions whose costs must be weighted against the benefits obtained by replacing the current tax system. 相似文献
996.
Martin Weiss Author Vitae Martin Junginger Author VitaeAuthor Vitae Kornelis Blok Author Vitae 《Technological Forecasting and Social Change》2010,77(3):411-8581
Transitioning towards a sustainable energy system requires the large-scale introduction of novel energy demand and supply technologies. Such novel technologies are often expensive at the point of their market introduction but eventually become cheaper due to technological learning. In order to quantify potentials for price and cost decline, the experience curve approach has been extensively applied to renewable and non-renewable energy supply technologies. However, its application to energy demand technologies is far less frequent. Here, we provide the first comprehensive review of experience curve analyses for energy demand technologies. We find a widespread trend towards declining prices and costs at an average learning rate of 18 ± 9%. This finding is consistent with the results for energy supply technologies and for manufacturing in general. Learning rates for individual energy demand technologies are symmetrically distributed around the arithmetic mean of the data sample. Absolute variation of learning rates within individual technology clusters of 7 ± 4%-points and between technology clusters of 7 ± 5%-points both contribute to the overall variability of learning rates. Our results show that technological learning is as important for energy demand technologies as it is for energy supply technologies. Applying the experience curve approach to forecast technology costs involves, however, unresolved uncertainties, as we demonstrate in a case study for the micro-cogeneration technology. 相似文献
997.
998.
The discipline of Operational Research (OR) is primarily concerned with improving the effectiveness and efficiency of decision processes. These processes take place everywhere in society: industry, banking, agriculture, government, politics. Frequent use of mathematical optimization models is typical of OR. Since the early '80s these models are increasingly packaged in a user-friendly way, as Decision Support Systems. In the following we will illustrate how OR can be used to describe and solve a number of environmental problems. 相似文献
999.
Jerry L. Petr 《Journal of economic issues》2013,47(2):561-569
Ireland has experienced a series of interlocking banking, fiscal, unemployment, and political crises since 2007. We detail the challenges involved in modeling individual moments of the crisis through the lens of balance sheets and transactions matrices among sectors of the Irish society. We conclude with a series of recommendations for models of small open economies. 相似文献
1000.
Letizia Mortara Simon J. FordAuthor VitaeManuel JaegerAuthor Vitae 《Technological Forecasting and Social Change》2013
Idea Competitions (ICs) are becoming a popular mechanism chosen by firms to perform Open Innovation. They are a way to engage with external sources of knowledge such as individual entrepreneurs and small firms who are asked to submit ideas and compete for a prize. However, little is known about the success of ICs as acquisition mechanisms. The researchers conducted interviews in five multinational companies to evaluate the effects of using ICs as an acquisition mechanism. Although still preliminary, the results of this study show that the success of ICs as an acquisition mechanism remains uncertain because their output (i.e. the number of ideas acquired) is often low compared to the input (i.e. the number of ideas submitted) and effort required to run them (e.g. to vet ideas). Across the cases observed, ICs appear to be more successful at identifying and acquiring early-stage ideas, particularly those outside the current business focus. The study shows that ICs deliver other functional benefits such as improved intelligence and public relations and that these need to be considered as part of the evaluation of the IC's success. The paper concludes by discussing the conditions in which ICs are implemented and the implications for Open Innovation theory. 相似文献