首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   814篇
  免费   14篇
财政金融   58篇
工业经济   95篇
计划管理   96篇
经济学   256篇
综合类   1篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   10篇
贸易经济   163篇
农业经济   22篇
经济概况   123篇
邮电经济   3篇
  2016年   6篇
  2015年   4篇
  2014年   7篇
  2013年   150篇
  2012年   20篇
  2011年   46篇
  2010年   28篇
  2008年   9篇
  2007年   6篇
  2006年   14篇
  2005年   20篇
  2004年   17篇
  2003年   8篇
  2002年   7篇
  2001年   6篇
  1999年   13篇
  1997年   10篇
  1996年   19篇
  1995年   4篇
  1994年   4篇
  1993年   39篇
  1992年   27篇
  1991年   24篇
  1990年   17篇
  1989年   14篇
  1988年   14篇
  1987年   24篇
  1986年   20篇
  1985年   15篇
  1984年   31篇
  1983年   8篇
  1982年   16篇
  1981年   12篇
  1980年   11篇
  1979年   8篇
  1978年   3篇
  1977年   7篇
  1976年   36篇
  1975年   11篇
  1974年   5篇
  1973年   3篇
  1971年   12篇
  1970年   16篇
  1967年   3篇
  1964年   4篇
  1963年   3篇
  1962年   6篇
  1961年   3篇
  1941年   3篇
  1872年   5篇
排序方式: 共有828条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
821.
For developing, technology-receiving countries, direct foreign investment is always better than licensing in the short run with sectoral immobility of capital. In the long run with perfect mobility of capital between sectors, the welfare rankings of the two scenarios are dependent upon the amount of domestic capital. The likely case is that the developing country would have a smaller amount of domestic capital than foreign investors, and hence licensing could yield higher national welfare.The authors are indebted to many useful comments of two anonymous referees. The authors, however, are solely responsible for any remaining shortcomings.  相似文献   
822.
Conclusion The main results of this paper provide some analytic underpinning for a strict horizontal merger policy relating to dominant firms. However, even under standard assumptions, examples have been demonstrated where dominant/fringe firm mergers increase welfare. Most of these examples imply shutting down acquired facilities, a practice regarded as unfavorable evidence by the court in theStandard Oil case; consequently, they do not by themselves seem to offer much hope for raising economies as an antitrust defense. Finally, it should be noted that this paper has considered only single-product economies; economies of scope arising in multi-product (and multi-market) contexts could be large enough to justify dominant/fringe firm mergers9.An earlier version of this paper was presented at the Economic Policy Office seminar, Antitrust Division, U. S. Department of Justice. The author is grateful to Marius Schwartz, other seminar participants and an anonymous referee of this journal for helpful comments. M. Daniel Westbrook and Brian Flynn kindly arranged for the calculations reported in Appendix C.  相似文献   
823.
824.
Despite major changes in the number and range of sources of finance for new and small ventures in the United Kingdom in recent years, there continues to be a shortage of risk capital for ventures actively seeking external equity finance. In the United States the informal venture capital market plays a major role in filling this equity gap, particularly in the early stages of venture development.However, there is little comparable information on the size of the informal venture capital pool in the United Kingdom or other European economies, despite recent recognition that the apparent underdevelopment of this market in the U.K. represents a major barrier to the development and growth of new ventures. This paper, therefore, presents the first analysis of the informal venture capital market in the U.K. and compares the characteristics and attitudes of U.K. informal investors with those in the U.S.The data reported in this paper have been obtained from a combination of postal survey and snowball sample techniques that generated useable information from 86 informal investors. Informal investors are playing an important role in venture financing in the U.K. in three ways: they make small scale investments in new and early stage ventures, where the equity gap is most significant; they are more permissive in their financing decisions than the formal venture capital industry in terms of having lower rejection rates, longer exit horizons, and lower target rates of return; and they invest locally and can thereby close the regional equity gap arising from the overconcentration of venture capital investment in the core South-East region in the U.K.In terms of demographics, U.K. informal investors share many of the characteristics of North American informal investors: they are predominantly male, with an entrepreneurial background, financially well-off without being super-rich, and identify investment opportunities from friends and business associates. There are a number of key differences, that may be attributable to differences in contextual factors such as personal tax regimes, regulatory environments, wealth distribution, and the structure of the formal venture capital and IPO markets. For example, U.K. informal investors are significantly older than those in the U.S. reflecting the influence of higher U.K. tax rates on the rate of capital and wealth accumulation.More generally, in comparison to U.S. investors, U.K. informal investors: have more investment opportunities brought to their attention; seriously consider more proposals but invest in no more opportunities; operate independently with syndication and joint investment relatively uncommon, reducing the average total investment per financing round available to ventures; fail to identify entrepreneurs themselves as a primary source of information on investment opportunities; have higher rate of return and capital gains expectations; are slightly less patient investors; and are rather less satisfied with the overall performance of their informal investment portfolios, reflecting intercountry and intertemporal variations in investment climate and conditions. It appears, therefore, that the general inefficiency of the informal capital market identified by Wetzel (1987) (which reflects the invisibility of informal investors, the fragmented nature of the market, and the imperfect channels of communication between investor and entrepreneur) is compounded in the U.K. case. The extent to which this reflects contextual differences on the one hand or simply a slower developmental process in the U.K. will only be common methodological basis. Based on the evidence presented in this paper, however, a key conclusion is that the information networks available to U.K. informal investors are less effective than those in North America, and in particular appear to contain lower quality information and a higher degree of redundant information. Specific forms of intervention in the market by, for example, stimulating the flow of information through the promotion of informal investment networking and brokerage services along the lines of U.S. and Canadian examples such as VCN and COIN therefore appear defensible.  相似文献   
825.
826.
This article reports on an experiment in external facilitation of international project marketing activity. The case involved a large, World Bank funded project in China aimed at upgrading grain storage and handling facilities. An organization was established in Australia to bring together and support efforts by Australian firms to win a share of this project. Network-building, at a number of levels both in China and Australia, emerged from the qualitative study as a critical factor in effective project marketing. External facilitation played a positive role in the network-building process.  相似文献   
827.
The Red de Semillas Libres (Network of Free Seeds) in Colombia contests the expansion of, and dominant narratives on, agricultural biotechnology and intellectual property rights (IPRs) protections on seed – or what has been called ‘biohegemony’. We argue that despite its challenges, the Network contests ‘biohegemony’ through lawsuits, supporting ‘seed sovereignty’, and reframing the often taken‐for‐granted discourse on local seed varieties as raw material and a resource to be ‘discovered’, ‘invented’ and commodified by industry and Western‐based technoscience. Based on ethnographic research, we extend the concept of biohegemony to include struggle and contestation by examining how the Network pursues seed sovereignty.  相似文献   
828.
中国传统的国家间信任思想及其启示   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
西方国际关系理论大多以国际社会无政府状态作为基本假设,对国家间信任没有给予足够的重视。然而,信任思想却是中国传统文化的主要内容之一。通过梳理中国传统的国家间信任思想以及借鉴社会学和心理学领域的信任理论,可以分别建构出以信用或信任作为自变量和因变量的因果理论以及以国家信用为中心的规范理论。中国先秦思想家认为:一方面,信用和信誉对一国的综合国力、相对权力、国家安全和战略成败等有着决定性的影响;信用和信任有助于国家间合作与友好,有助于同盟的建立和维持。另一方面,利益、透明度和信用等都是影响信任产生的关键因素。国家间信任理论对当代中国外交提供了许多有益的启示。将国家信用作为一项长期的对外战略,增加对外决策和对外战略的透明度,加强诚信政府建设,维持与周边国家的友好关系,积极参与国际组织和国际机制的建设,加强中国传统国际政治与外交思想的研究和宣传,这些措施将会有助于增加中国的国际信用、树立良好的国家信誉形象以及与周边邻国和主要大国构建互信关系。  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号