首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   614篇
  免费   23篇
  国内免费   1篇
财政金融   106篇
工业经济   57篇
计划管理   110篇
经济学   153篇
综合类   15篇
运输经济   12篇
旅游经济   22篇
贸易经济   121篇
农业经济   7篇
经济概况   35篇
  2023年   2篇
  2022年   1篇
  2021年   8篇
  2020年   7篇
  2019年   22篇
  2018年   10篇
  2017年   23篇
  2016年   13篇
  2015年   18篇
  2014年   14篇
  2013年   68篇
  2012年   15篇
  2011年   28篇
  2010年   22篇
  2009年   28篇
  2008年   18篇
  2007年   21篇
  2006年   24篇
  2005年   10篇
  2004年   24篇
  2003年   19篇
  2002年   19篇
  2001年   20篇
  2000年   17篇
  1999年   20篇
  1998年   26篇
  1997年   14篇
  1996年   11篇
  1995年   4篇
  1994年   10篇
  1993年   8篇
  1992年   12篇
  1991年   8篇
  1990年   8篇
  1989年   5篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   2篇
  1986年   4篇
  1985年   11篇
  1984年   6篇
  1983年   6篇
  1982年   3篇
  1980年   5篇
  1979年   5篇
  1978年   6篇
  1977年   2篇
  1976年   3篇
  1974年   2篇
  1973年   1篇
  1961年   2篇
排序方式: 共有638条查询结果,搜索用时 46 毫秒
111.
This paper analyzes the welfare implications of fixed-price regulation of services in a model in which consumers are heterogenous and a firm can endogenously quality discriminate. We consider two different scenarios: The first scenario is when the consumer is also the payer. The second scenario is when the payer (usually the government) is not the consumer. Our major result is that fixed-price regulation causes a distributional welfare loss. We show that it is not possible for fixed-price regulation to induce providers to supply all consumer types with the first-best quality even under perfect information, under either pricing scenario. We show that high and low demand types may receive more than their respective first-best qualities, less than their first-best qualities, or one type may receive more and the other type less depending on the level of the regulated price. It is always true that when consumers are payers, quality is higher for both types than when consumers are not the payers. In this paper, we motivate and discuss the results in terms of price regulation of hospitals where consumers are patients and patient types vary by severity of illness.  相似文献   
112.
Commitment and matching contributions to public goods   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
We study multi-stage processes of non-cooperative voluntary provision of public goods. In the first stage, one or more players announce contributions that may be conditional on the subsequent contributions of others. In later stages, players choose their own contributions and fulfill any commitments made in the first stage. Equilibrium contributions are characterized under different assumptions about the commitment ability of players, the number of public goods and whether players commit to matching rates or to discrete quantities. We focus on contribution mechanisms that can emerge and be sustainable without a central authority, and that may be particularly relevant for international public goods. Efficient levels of public goods can be achieved under some circumstances, while in others commitment is ineffective.  相似文献   
113.
Data on 4,087 securities from 1988 to 1990 are used to test the relation between market model R2 and trading volume. Eliminating high-volume observations increases R2 by about 10 percent, confirming results previously reported. This study indicates that this improvement is possible by eliminating a small number of observations. It also indicates that this relation between R2 and volume is unrelated to firm size.  相似文献   
114.
115.
116.
117.
abstract In a qualitative interview study, 20 Hong Kong Chinese informants were asked to report stories about colleagues who were either ‘good soldiers’ or ‘good actors’. In stories about good soldiers, informants attributed their colleagues' organizational citizenship behaviour (OCB) primarily to prosocial or pro‐organizational motives. Informants' stories about good actors broke down into three major subcategories of citizenship‐related impression management: OCB attributed primarily to impression management motives; alleged pseudo‐OCB concomitant with minimal compliance; and alleged pseudo‐OCB concomitant with counterproductive behaviour. When distinguishing good soldiers from good actors, informants adopted two criteria for attribution: wilful behavioural inconsistency, i.e. low generality of behaviour across contexts; and alleged false pretence, i.e. discrepancy between claims or allusions and actual deeds. Our findings partially supported a prior hypothesis from attribution theory, that consistency was a criterion for attribution, but indicated that consensus, i.e. correspondence between the focal colleague's behaviour and other employees' behaviour, failed to differentiate good soldiers from good actors. Informants generally regarded OCB as socially desirable only when it was attributed primarily to prosocial/pro‐organizational motives.  相似文献   
118.
Grapevine     
Robin Sharp 《Food Policy》1985,10(4):300-301
  相似文献   
119.
This paper examines criminal choice using a variant of the human capital model. The innovation of our approach is that it attempts to disaggregate individual capital, not unlike production-based studies which disaggregate physical capital into equipment and structures. We disaggregate an individual’s capital stock into the standard human capital component as well as a utility generating component that we call social capital. In our set-up, social capital is used to account for the influence of social norms on the decision to participate in crime. This is done by modeling the stigma of arrest as a reduction in the individual’s social capital stock. We also allow individuals to account for the impact of their criminal actions on their probability of arrest. In order to estimate the structural parameters underlying the model, we make use of computationally intensive methods involving simulated generalized method of moments and value function approximation. The empirical results, based on panel data from the Delinquency in a Birth Cohort II Study, support the social capital model of crime and reveal significant state dependence in the decision to participate in crime.  相似文献   
120.
In 1957, Farrell introduced a nonparametric method to estimate technical efficiency. His original illustration, however, utilized value-based, rather than quantity-based data (p. 279). This common practice raises the question of how value-based DEA models coincide with quantity-based models. It is well known that the two models coincide when firms face identical prices. In practice, however, prices vary across firms and the two models yield materially different results. We decompose the resulting difference into its technology and firm-related components and then use Farrell’s original data set to show that the expected difference is systematic and one-sided.   相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号