首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   17097篇
  免费   442篇
财政金融   3301篇
工业经济   1428篇
计划管理   2840篇
经济学   3618篇
综合类   176篇
运输经济   148篇
旅游经济   322篇
贸易经济   2655篇
农业经济   811篇
经济概况   2234篇
信息产业经济   1篇
邮电经济   5篇
  2021年   116篇
  2020年   195篇
  2019年   251篇
  2018年   356篇
  2017年   355篇
  2016年   323篇
  2015年   223篇
  2014年   369篇
  2013年   1871篇
  2012年   498篇
  2011年   516篇
  2010年   500篇
  2009年   558篇
  2008年   481篇
  2007年   424篇
  2006年   401篇
  2005年   338篇
  2004年   342篇
  2003年   358篇
  2002年   339篇
  2001年   339篇
  2000年   374篇
  1999年   311篇
  1998年   301篇
  1997年   326篇
  1996年   304篇
  1995年   261篇
  1994年   269篇
  1993年   298篇
  1992年   275篇
  1991年   265篇
  1990年   264篇
  1989年   237篇
  1988年   229篇
  1987年   219篇
  1986年   243篇
  1985年   328篇
  1984年   306篇
  1983年   299篇
  1982年   252篇
  1981年   240篇
  1980年   261篇
  1979年   219篇
  1978年   188篇
  1977年   180篇
  1976年   152篇
  1975年   140篇
  1974年   118篇
  1973年   124篇
  1972年   93篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 406 毫秒
61.
Conclusion The article provides a contribution to the discussion on the net foreign assets of the commerical banks, by drawing renewed attention to the possible passivity of the banking sector, which has gained topicality with the striking developments of 1989. Indeed, the banking sector may be considerably more reactive in regards to net foreign assets formation than has been assumed by various authors and in macroeconometric models on the basis of portfolio optimizing behaviour. However, due to the above-mentioned methodological and empirical shortcomings, Bakkers's study certainly does not provide the final answer to this question.  相似文献   
62.
专门化、多样化和中国地区工业产业增长的关系   总被引:18,自引:2,他引:16  
本文通过分析中国29个省(除西藏外)的30个工业产业在1988-1997期间的数据。揭示了工业结构和经济增长之间的关系。本文除研究了传统的生产要素的影响外,重点探讨了产业专门化、专业多样化、竞争度和一省发展的初始水平等因素的作用。结果表明,一个产业外部工业环境的多样性和产业内的竞争度有利于产业的增长,但产业专门影响为负。工业结构对于增长的影响在很大程度上依赖于产业的性质及其地理位置。  相似文献   
63.
64.
We model an accession country facing a Maastricht‐type inflation criterion that specifies an inflation ceiling. In addition to deciding whether or not to satisfy this criterion, the country must decide how much costly economic reform to undertake. If the country puts enough weight on the future that it can credibly meet the inflation criterion no matter what the ceiling is, then the inflation criterion benefits the country but lowers reform. If the country puts less weight on the future, then a criterion with a properly chosen inflation ceiling can increase reform. We derive the inflation ceilings that maximize the country's welfare and its reform.  相似文献   
65.
Tort reform of the motor accident insurance compensation scheme in the Australian state of New South Wales in 1999 came about as a result of an untested experiment in regulatory negotiation. This article is a first-hand account of the successful attempt to craft a consensual modification of the scheme through deliberations among a working group of service provider representatives. The author, a Canadian lawyer, investigated the prospects for change, acted as chief negotiator, and observed the legislative process that led to the final law reform.  相似文献   
66.
Nelson and Plosser (1982), in a classic paper, failed to find strong evidence against the null hypothesis of a generating process with a unit autoregressive root for thirteen US macroeconomic time series. Perron (1989) claimed that such evidence was available for a majority of these series if the alternative hypothesis was of trend stationarity with a break in 1929. Zivot and Andrews (1992) treated the break date as endogenous, then finding strong evidence agcainst the null for a minority of these series. Our own analysis extends theirs by permitting a break under the null as well as the alternative hypothesis, and allowing for the sequential nature of the testing. Our empirical findings complete the circle. We find no strong evidence against the unit root hypothesis for any of the thirteen Nelson–Plosser series.  相似文献   
67.
Employment Contacts and Minority-White Wage Differences   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
We study effects of job contacts on wages in inner-city Boston in 1989 and in the 1982 NLSY. Race/Hispanicity differences in wages are not explained by an absence of contacts among minority youths. Rather, in the Boston data, lower wages of black youths are explained by lower "returns" to their contacts. In the NLSY there is little evidence of lower return to black youths' contacts, but there is evidence of lower returns to Hispanic youths' contacts.  相似文献   
68.
69.
Large Non-Union Companies: How Do They Avoid a Catch 22?   总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1  
Large non-union companies might be expected to enjoy extensive work-force flexibility deriving from their high-wage, high-involvement strategies. However, where there is a strong local union presence, this might be expected to exert a strong dampening effect on the levels of internal flexibility achieved. Such companies, fearful of union organization, could not then enjoy the freedoms that might be associated with a non-union strategy. Research conducted in the Republic of Ireland on large non-union US companies operating in the electronics industry suggests a conceptual framework indicating how a Catch-22 situation is avoided in these companies.  相似文献   
70.
We propose that analysis of purchasing power parity (PPP) and the law of one price should explicitly take into account the possibility of “commodity points”—thresholds delineating a region of no central tendency among relative prices, possibly due to lack of perfect arbitrage in the presence of transaction costs and uncertainty. More than 80 years ago, Heckscher stressed the importance of such incomplete arbitrage in the empirical application of PPP. We devise an econometric method to identify commodity points. Price adjustment is treated as a nonlinear process, and a threshold autoregression offers a parsimonious specification within which both thresholds and adjustment speeds are estimated by maximum likelihood methods. Our model performs well using post-1980 data, and yields parameter estimates that appear quite reasonable: adjustment outside the thresholds might imply half-lives of price deviations measured in months rather than years, and the thresholds correspond to popular rough estimates as to the order of magnitude of actual transport costs. The estimated commodity points appear to be positively related to objective measures of market segmentation, notably nominal exchange rate volatility.J. Japan Int. Econ.December 1997,11(4), pp. 441–479. Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, California 94720-3880; and Department of Economics, Northwestern University, Evanston, Illinois 60208-2600.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号