全文获取类型
收费全文 | 278篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 32篇 |
工业经济 | 11篇 |
计划管理 | 117篇 |
经济学 | 43篇 |
综合类 | 9篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 32篇 |
农业经济 | 1篇 |
经济概况 | 30篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 2篇 |
2019年 | 3篇 |
2018年 | 7篇 |
2017年 | 5篇 |
2016年 | 2篇 |
2015年 | 2篇 |
2014年 | 4篇 |
2013年 | 19篇 |
2012年 | 19篇 |
2011年 | 7篇 |
2010年 | 47篇 |
2009年 | 58篇 |
2008年 | 9篇 |
2007年 | 8篇 |
2006年 | 8篇 |
2005年 | 15篇 |
2004年 | 2篇 |
2003年 | 29篇 |
2002年 | 4篇 |
2001年 | 1篇 |
2000年 | 1篇 |
1999年 | 2篇 |
1998年 | 2篇 |
1997年 | 2篇 |
1996年 | 1篇 |
1995年 | 2篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1990年 | 2篇 |
1983年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 1篇 |
1980年 | 1篇 |
1979年 | 1篇 |
1972年 | 1篇 |
1971年 | 1篇 |
1969年 | 3篇 |
1968年 | 1篇 |
1967年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有278条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
31.
32.
By Ingvar Johansson 《American journal of economics and sociology》2003,62(1):233-255
A BSTRACT . One aim of this paper is to make visible the connection between Searle's views on social reality and his general ontology, and at the same time to show that some peculiar features of his analysis of social reality are a natural outcome of his general ontology. The paper contains five sections. In the first Searle's naturalism is philosophically situated and its differentia specifica explained. Then, Searle's view that intentional states exist only in brains is presented. One might say that, according to Searle, each mind is, although caused by a material brain, a Leibnizian monad. This view is related to an important, but neglected, distinction that Searle himself has made between requirement conditions of satisfaction and required conditions of satisfaction. In the third section, it is pointed out that, necessarily, sometimes there has to exist some kind of relation of satisfaction between the two kinds of conditions of satisfaction. Searle, however, has never really discussed what this satisfaction relation may look like. The upshot of all the remarks is that, fourth, Searle's general ontology automatically implies an ontology of social reality according to which a social fact can only exist as a scattered aggregate whose items exist in the brains of the people who constitute it. Finally and fifth, I try to think with Searle against Searle. His monadological view of social reality cannot, Searle notwithstanding, be regarded as being close to the direct realism of common sense. Searle's realism is an indirect realism. However, if Searle's view that intentional states exist only in brains is rejected, then the rest of his ontology has features that may take us closer to a direct realism. Such a move, which in one respect takes us closer to common sense, takes us in another respect away from common sense. The title of the last section is "Social Reality and the Impossibility of Common Sense." 相似文献
33.
Current discussions of climate change are overly focused on the science underpinning environmental impact, with little attention to socioeconomic consequences. The economics of environmental change in particular is insufficiently informed by the lessons that past experiences can yield. Drawing on case studies from Europe and Asia, this special issue underlines the importance of historical context, as well as markets, institutions, technology, and the role of international trade in understanding how economic systems have responded to environmental changes. Past economies have responded dynamically to environmental change rather than simply constrained deterministically by the climatic and ecological events that have engulfed them. 相似文献
34.
By INDRAJIT RAY 《The Economic history review》2009,62(4):857-892
This article seeks to answer three basic questions about the nineteenth‐century cotton textile industry in Bengal that still remain unresolved in the literature; namely, when did the industry begin to decay, what was the extent of its decay during the early nineteenth century, and what were the factors that led to this? In the absence of data on production, this article seeks to settle the debate on the basis of the industry's market performance and its consumption of raw materials. It contests the prevailing hypothesis that the industry's perpetual decline started in the late eighteenth or the early nineteenth century. Instead, it is argued that the decline started around the mid‐1820s. The pace of its decline was, however, slow though steady at the beginning, but reached crisis point by 1860, when around 563,000 workers lost their jobs. Regarding the extent of its decay, this article concludes that the industry was diminished by about 28 per cent by the mid‐1800s. However, it survived in the high‐end and low‐end domestic markets. Evidence is also gathered in favour of the hypothesis that, although British discriminatory policies undoubtedly depressed the industry's export outlet, its decay is better explained by technological innovations in Great Britain. 相似文献
35.
This paper offers an overview of the literature on the economic and financial applications of theory of nonlinear dynamics, especially bifurcation theory. After a short introductory discussion of the first nonlinear dynamic models in social sciences and the economic relevance of the zoo of bifurcations and complicated dynamics that such models can generate, we present an overview of the literature on nonlinear dynamic models in the areas of underdevelopment, environmental poverty traps, the management of common goods, industrial organization and financial markets. The review of the literature is enriched by reflections and ideas for future research. 相似文献
36.
Mikhail S. Kouliavtsev 《Review of Industrial Organization》2007,30(1):1-27
This paper suggests an innovative measure of structural relief obtained in a typical Section 7 settlement. The fraction of
competitive overlap subject to divestiture as a condition of the settlement is modeled as a function of merger-specific efficiencies,
the proportion of the deal held “hostage” to antitrust review, the merger’s anticompetitive potential, and other factors.
The model is applied to data on 86 recent Justice Department cases covering the period 1990–2003 and to the subsample of 1990s
cases. All data are collected from publicly available documents only. The government is found to secure larger divestitures
when the cost to the acquirer of delaying the settlement is high. The resulting estimates are used to predict several out-of-sample
observations.
I would like to thank the General Editor and two anonymous referees for many helpful suggestions on earlier drafts of this
paper. The remaining errors are mine. 相似文献
37.
A bstract In his comment on Victor Fuch's essay, the late Alvan Feinstein raised the question of whether government-sponsored programs of "health promotion" are always good for well-being. 相似文献
38.
The disclosure of non-GAAP (pro forma) earnings numbers by managers in the post-SOX era continues to attract attention from regulators, media, and researchers. However, there is limited empirical evidence on how auditors view clients that emphasize pro forma earnings over GAAP earnings. We study the extent to which audit fees and auditor resignations are associated with opportunistic non-GAAP disclosures. We find that during the pre-SOX period, optimistic pro forma differences, measured using either IBES actual earnings or hand-collected pro forma earnings, are associated with higher audit fees and a higher likelihood of auditor resignations. Additional results indicate that auditors seem to be more concerned with non-GAAP earnings disclosures in the post-SOX period. 相似文献
39.
Patricia Klarner Rune Todnem By Thomas Diefenbach 《Scandinavian Journal of Management》2011,27(3):332-340
In this research note, we address the role of employee emotions during organizational change processes. While prior studies have examined emotions during a single change, such research analyzes emotions and change as snapshot events. In addition, we lack sufficient knowledge of the role of employee emotions during repeated changes, despite the evidence that organizations increasingly need to adapt to dynamic environments. We address these shortcomings and offer a research agenda on emotions during change, which incorporates the so far neglected view of emotions as processes that unfold during and across organizational changes. Specifically, we illustrate the role of employee emotions during sequential and simultaneous changes and offer six suggestions for future research on emotions in such contexts. 相似文献
40.
Collective Intentions and Collective Intentionality 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
By L.A. Zaibert 《American journal of economics and sociology》2003,62(1):209-232
A BSTRACT . John Searle believes that collective intentions are crucial to his philosophy, but he is yet to present a coherent account of these entities. No account whatsoever of collective intentions is presented in the book where Searle needs them the most ( The Construction of Social Reality ), or, for that matter, in any other of Searle's major books. The only account, and a defective one at that (so I argue), is found in a short, somewhat obscure article entitled "Collective Intentions and Actions," but in fact what Searle presents there is, at best, an account of collective actions , not of collective intentions. In light of Searle own ground-breaking work in the philosophy of mind, and in particular in light of his far-reaching analyses showing how intentions differ from related mental states, I argue that collective intentions are not consistent with Searle's philosophy of mind. 相似文献