全文获取类型
收费全文 | 16933篇 |
免费 | 393篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 3293篇 |
工业经济 | 1410篇 |
计划管理 | 2851篇 |
经济学 | 3561篇 |
综合类 | 179篇 |
运输经济 | 129篇 |
旅游经济 | 309篇 |
贸易经济 | 2567篇 |
农业经济 | 768篇 |
经济概况 | 2254篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 4篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 119篇 |
2020年 | 203篇 |
2019年 | 263篇 |
2018年 | 365篇 |
2017年 | 357篇 |
2016年 | 332篇 |
2015年 | 239篇 |
2014年 | 376篇 |
2013年 | 1895篇 |
2012年 | 525篇 |
2011年 | 562篇 |
2010年 | 507篇 |
2009年 | 580篇 |
2008年 | 511篇 |
2007年 | 430篇 |
2006年 | 396篇 |
2005年 | 341篇 |
2004年 | 345篇 |
2003年 | 356篇 |
2002年 | 334篇 |
2001年 | 326篇 |
2000年 | 359篇 |
1999年 | 320篇 |
1998年 | 289篇 |
1997年 | 303篇 |
1996年 | 277篇 |
1995年 | 244篇 |
1994年 | 237篇 |
1993年 | 279篇 |
1992年 | 258篇 |
1991年 | 264篇 |
1990年 | 251篇 |
1989年 | 228篇 |
1988年 | 210篇 |
1987年 | 190篇 |
1986年 | 224篇 |
1985年 | 306篇 |
1984年 | 283篇 |
1983年 | 279篇 |
1982年 | 231篇 |
1981年 | 230篇 |
1980年 | 250篇 |
1979年 | 203篇 |
1978年 | 177篇 |
1977年 | 178篇 |
1976年 | 147篇 |
1975年 | 136篇 |
1974年 | 113篇 |
1973年 | 113篇 |
1972年 | 84篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
971.
James H. Gilkeson Sylvia C. Hudgins Craig K. Ruff 《Journal of Economics and Finance》1997,21(2):27-37
A depository institution's interest rate risk (IRR) exposure is the sensitivity of its earnings or market value of equity to changes in interest rates. Since the mid-1980's, bank regulators have developed broadly applied, centralized IRR models which are used to help assess individual institutions' capital adequacy. This paper tests the effectiveness of the earliest of these regulatory IRR models: the incomegap estimates calculated by the Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB) during the latter 1980's. Despite the many problems caused by the broad application of generic assumptions and the presence of embedded options, we find that the FHLBB gap estimates provided a significant measure of IRR exposure. We believe that these results bode well for the success of ongoing, more sophisticated regulatory modeling efforts. 相似文献
972.
Joshua C.C. Chan 《International Journal of Forecasting》2021,37(3):1212-1226
Large Bayesian VARs with stochastic volatility are increasingly used in empirical macroeconomics. The key to making these highly parameterized VARs useful is the use of shrinkage priors. We develop a family of priors that captures the best features of two prominent classes of shrinkage priors: adaptive hierarchical priors and Minnesota priors. Like adaptive hierarchical priors, these new priors ensure that only ‘small’ coefficients are strongly shrunk to zero, while ‘large’ coefficients remain intact. At the same time, these new priors can also incorporate many useful features of the Minnesota priors such as cross-variable shrinkage and shrinking coefficients on higher lags more aggressively. We introduce a fast posterior sampler to estimate BVARs with this family of priors—for a BVAR with 25 variables and 4 lags, obtaining 10,000 posterior draws takes about 3 min on a standard desktop computer. In a forecasting exercise, we show that these new priors outperform both adaptive hierarchical priors and Minnesota priors. 相似文献
973.
Clarence C. Morrison 《Atlantic Economic Journal》1995,23(3):189-202
This paper implements numerically a general equilibrium model in which all private producers are price makers and the government
utilizes tax revenues to provide a public good. After deriving the partial equilibrium condition for an excise tax to increase
price by more than the tax (for a monopoly firm), numerical examples are given, demonstrating this phenomenon for both partial
and general equilibrium. In the general equilibrium context, optimal excise taxation and optimal flat-rate income taxation
are compared. In the excise tax regime, prices increase by more than the taxes. In the income tax regime, prices actually
decline relative to the no-tax regime. In all of the examples given, flat-rate income taxation is superior to excise taxation
in terms of welfare.
The author has benefitted from exceptionally helpful comments received from J. Ronnie Davis, John D. Wilson, Ralph W. Pfouts,
and Amy Crews. He has also benefitted from conversations with Franz Gehrels, David E. Wildasin, Herbert J. Kiesling, and Harold
York. The usual disclaimer applies. 相似文献
974.
The present paper describes the benefits and costs, in qualitative terms, of managing food price instability in Asia in the context of promoting economic growth and poverty reduction to improve food security. The experience of Asian governments in actual practice with price stabilization is discussed in the context of managing an efficient transition to market‐mediated food security. Recent experience in Indonesia, where a sharp increase in rice prices (caused by a ban on rice imports) pushed 4 million people into poverty, provides continued motivation for the analytical story in this paper. 相似文献
975.
In 1993, Californians voted on a school voucher initiative. We hypothesize that homeowners in good school districts understood the voucher to be a threat to their property values and thus voted against it. Precinct returns from Los Angeles County confirm this hypothesis. We also examine an alternative hypothesis explaining the relationship between school quality and precinct returns. According to the alternative, voters perceived the initiative to be a referendum on public school quality. To distinguish between the two hypotheses, we compare the voting patterns of homeowners and renters. The comparison does not favor one hypothesis over the other. 相似文献
976.
977.
978.
K.C. Fung 《Global Economic Review》2015,44(4):376-386
AbstractIn this paper, I examine the economic links first between the European Union (EU) and China and then I focus on the economic relationships between Germany and China. The links I will consider include international trade and direct investment. Lastly I highlight some elements of the so-called “German Model” or the “Berlin Way” and examine if they can be of policy relevance to China. There are four main results: first, EU-China trade and investment relationships are strong, deepening rapidly but they are somewhat unbalanced and asymmetric. Second, the economic relationships between Europe and China are focused on manufacturing. Third, the EU-China relationships are primarily Deutschland-centric. Lastly, elements of the “German Model” such as Mitbestimmung, Mittelstand and the German apprenticeship system can have important structural and policy implications as China continues to grow and experiment with reforms aiming at combining stability, harmony and competitiveness. 相似文献
979.
Managers frequently attribute the news in their earnings forecasts to various economic events. Using textual analysis, we identify the economic factors underlying earnings news from press releases. We document a wide range of industry‐wide shocks and firm‐specific actions to which the earnings news in management forecasts is attributed. As expected, earnings attributions significantly affect peer firms’ price reactions to the earnings news. Specifically, earnings news attributed to industry‐wide trends or firm structural changes leads to positive information transfers but earnings news attributed to firm competitive moves triggers negative information transfers. Information transfers are much stronger when each economic factor is mentioned the first time in a given industry‐year. Further analysis reveals that the strength of information transfers varies with firm‐level rivalry within the industry (i.e., similar business strategies, market position, and level of competition). 相似文献
980.
Temple (2002) argues that the inflation level used in Romer (1993) lacks power in revealing the policy intentions of monetary authorities, Temple also points out that Romer's use of the openness-inflation correlation cannot be explained by time consistency theory. In this article, we demonstrate that more open economies experience less inflation volatility and persislence. We attribute our findings to the hypothesis that monetary authorities in more open economies adopt more aggressive monetary policies. This pattern emerges strongly after 1990. Our results indicate that the near-universal regime shift in 1990 is not just a simple process of increased monetary policy aggressiveness, but an increased response to economic openness. 相似文献