首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   627篇
  免费   4篇
财政金融   150篇
工业经济   41篇
计划管理   118篇
经济学   122篇
综合类   6篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   14篇
贸易经济   119篇
农业经济   27篇
经济概况   33篇
  2023年   4篇
  2021年   5篇
  2020年   13篇
  2019年   7篇
  2018年   9篇
  2017年   20篇
  2016年   16篇
  2015年   8篇
  2014年   12篇
  2013年   85篇
  2012年   28篇
  2011年   27篇
  2010年   18篇
  2009年   9篇
  2008年   16篇
  2007年   17篇
  2006年   20篇
  2005年   12篇
  2004年   10篇
  2003年   12篇
  2002年   17篇
  2001年   17篇
  2000年   10篇
  1999年   15篇
  1998年   8篇
  1997年   9篇
  1996年   15篇
  1995年   11篇
  1994年   7篇
  1993年   9篇
  1992年   10篇
  1991年   7篇
  1990年   8篇
  1989年   7篇
  1988年   6篇
  1987年   5篇
  1986年   7篇
  1985年   8篇
  1984年   11篇
  1983年   8篇
  1982年   4篇
  1981年   8篇
  1980年   5篇
  1979年   9篇
  1978年   10篇
  1977年   8篇
  1975年   5篇
  1974年   4篇
  1971年   12篇
  1966年   3篇
排序方式: 共有631条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
151.
The cost-effectiveness of the KyotoProtocol and any similar non-global treatywould be enhanced by attracting additionalcountries to international emissions tradingand achieving this as soon as possible. Incontrast to what is heard in most of thedebate, such an enlargement is here taken to beattained with the new participants, atleast to begin with, being fullycompensated. This paper focuses on twoforms of compensation that can be used toattract poor countries to participate inemissions trading. The theoretical aswell as experimental evidence suggests that, ifpoor countries are more risk averse than richcountries, partial compensation in terms offinancial transfers is more cost-effective thanrelying solely on compensation in kind –emission quotas – as has been the case so far.Using money for partial compensation would alsoreduce the risk for ``hot air' allocations andthe ensuing political obstacles tocost-effectiveness that such allocations tendto create.  相似文献   
152.
California has adopted a policy of mandatory reductions in greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions to 1990 levels by the year 2020. (California Legislature (2006) Assembly Bill 32, the Global Warming Solutions Act of 2006, California Air Resources Board (2008) Climate change draft scoping plan, Sect. 2) Electricity utilities will need to recover related expenses, such as for the purchase of emissions permits. Economists often assume that raising usage prices for the commodity is the best way to recoup such expenses. However, regulated usage prices to California residential customers already exceed the cost of electricity generation plus a plausible externality cost for carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions. Instead, recovering compliance expenses through usage insensitive charges could avoid causing unnecessary economic harm to consumers.  相似文献   
153.
Carl Marklund 《Geopolitics》2017,22(3):623-639
This article analyses the contemporary deployment of the Nordic welfare state model as a centrepiece of Nordic competitive identity and strategic communication on the global market of ideas. First, it looks at the interrelated phenomena of global competition, competitive identity and region branding. Second, it studies the interplay between Nordic transnational public diplomacy and national public diplomacy of individual Nordic countries, in particular Sweden, on the one hand and international media outlets’ reporting on the Nordic countries on the other. In analysing this cross-fertilizing genre, the article identifies how the welfare state is being repackaged for export along with a set of “progressive values” which are coded as specifically “Nordic.” The article discusses (1) the interaction between outer images and inner visions; (2) the place and significance of the Nordic model, progressive values and the welfare state in today’s Nordic branding; and (3) the possible function of outward competitive identity as a kind of “compensatory imagination” directed inward as well as outward.  相似文献   
154.
Morgenstern et al. (J Environ Econ Manag 43:412–436, 2002. doi: 10.1006/jeem.2001.1191) are well-known for its investigation of the employment effects of environmental regulations. However, the cost function specified in that paper is handicapped by its reliance on survey data of the costs of inputs assigned to pollution abatement. In this paper, we specify an input distance function that models the joint production of good and bad outputs. This allows us to measure the relative importance of factors associated with changes in employment without pollution abatement cost data. We operationalize our model using a sample of 80 coal-fired electric power plants from 1995 to 2005.  相似文献   
155.
Using a linked employer–employee dataset covering large firms, we present new evidence on British wage inequality trends over the past two decades. Differences between firms in the average wages they paid did not drive these trends. Between 1996 and 2005, greater wage variance within firms accounted for 86% of the total increase in wage variance among employees. In the following decade, wage inequality between firms continued to increase, whereas overall wage dispersion decreased. Approximately all the contribution to inequality dynamics from estimated firm-specific factors, throughout the employee wage distribution, disappears after accounting for the changing occupational content of wages.  相似文献   
156.
Reworking published 1981 Census of Canada data, the authors initially present—for all ethnic communities of significant size (40.000+ nationally)—information on mother tongue, language spoken most often at home, and place of birth. Comparable provincial and CMA data is then provided. The authors conclude that marketers must supplement Census data with knowledge of such factors as the relative strength of ethnic affiliations and the drawing power of ethnic media. Custom designed studies of ethnic purchase and consumption patterns are also considered essential.  相似文献   
157.
Multinationals often serve foreign markets by exporting as well as by investing directly in foreign production facilities. We argue that if the multinational competes in an oligopolistic market characterized by strategic complements then there are strategic reasons to use two production facilities—committing to a second source allows the firm to keep average cost low while increasing its marginal cost. The increase in marginal cost softens product market competition resulting in higher profits. We argue that this theory also has implications for the “make or buy” literature in production management and the literature on second sourcing in industrial organization.  相似文献   
158.
Review of Industrial Organization - We study how the courts have responded to the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines issued by the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission....  相似文献   
159.
160.
Abstract

A. Confluent Hypergeometric Functions

The theory of such functions will be recapitulated here following a recently published book (Slater, L. J., Confluent Hypergeometric Functions, Cambr. Univ. Press 1960).  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号