全文获取类型
收费全文 | 627篇 |
免费 | 4篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 150篇 |
工业经济 | 41篇 |
计划管理 | 118篇 |
经济学 | 122篇 |
综合类 | 6篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 14篇 |
贸易经济 | 119篇 |
农业经济 | 27篇 |
经济概况 | 33篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 4篇 |
2021年 | 5篇 |
2020年 | 13篇 |
2019年 | 7篇 |
2018年 | 9篇 |
2017年 | 20篇 |
2016年 | 16篇 |
2015年 | 8篇 |
2014年 | 12篇 |
2013年 | 85篇 |
2012年 | 28篇 |
2011年 | 27篇 |
2010年 | 18篇 |
2009年 | 9篇 |
2008年 | 16篇 |
2007年 | 17篇 |
2006年 | 20篇 |
2005年 | 12篇 |
2004年 | 10篇 |
2003年 | 12篇 |
2002年 | 17篇 |
2001年 | 17篇 |
2000年 | 10篇 |
1999年 | 15篇 |
1998年 | 8篇 |
1997年 | 9篇 |
1996年 | 15篇 |
1995年 | 11篇 |
1994年 | 7篇 |
1993年 | 9篇 |
1992年 | 10篇 |
1991年 | 7篇 |
1990年 | 8篇 |
1989年 | 7篇 |
1988年 | 6篇 |
1987年 | 5篇 |
1986年 | 7篇 |
1985年 | 8篇 |
1984年 | 11篇 |
1983年 | 8篇 |
1982年 | 4篇 |
1981年 | 8篇 |
1980年 | 5篇 |
1979年 | 9篇 |
1978年 | 10篇 |
1977年 | 8篇 |
1975年 | 5篇 |
1974年 | 4篇 |
1971年 | 12篇 |
1966年 | 3篇 |
排序方式: 共有631条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
151.
The cost-effectiveness of the KyotoProtocol and any similar non-global treatywould be enhanced by attracting additionalcountries to international emissions tradingand achieving this as soon as possible. Incontrast to what is heard in most of thedebate, such an enlargement is here taken to beattained with the new participants, atleast to begin with, being fullycompensated. This paper focuses on twoforms of compensation that can be used toattract poor countries to participate inemissions trading. The theoretical aswell as experimental evidence suggests that, ifpoor countries are more risk averse than richcountries, partial compensation in terms offinancial transfers is more cost-effective thanrelying solely on compensation in kind –emission quotas – as has been the case so far.Using money for partial compensation would alsoreduce the risk for ``hot air' allocations andthe ensuing political obstacles tocost-effectiveness that such allocations tendto create. 相似文献
152.
Carl Danner 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》2010,37(1):98-106
California has adopted a policy of mandatory reductions in greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions to 1990 levels by the year 2020. (California Legislature (2006) Assembly Bill 32, the Global Warming Solutions Act of 2006, California Air Resources Board (2008) Climate change draft scoping plan, Sect. 2) Electricity utilities will need to recover related expenses, such as for the purchase of emissions permits. Economists often assume that raising usage prices for the commodity is the best way to recoup such expenses. However, regulated usage prices to California residential customers already exceed the cost of electricity generation plus a plausible externality cost for carbon dioxide (CO2) emissions. Instead, recovering compliance expenses through usage insensitive charges could avoid causing unnecessary economic harm to consumers. 相似文献
153.
Carl Marklund 《Geopolitics》2017,22(3):623-639
This article analyses the contemporary deployment of the Nordic welfare state model as a centrepiece of Nordic competitive identity and strategic communication on the global market of ideas. First, it looks at the interrelated phenomena of global competition, competitive identity and region branding. Second, it studies the interplay between Nordic transnational public diplomacy and national public diplomacy of individual Nordic countries, in particular Sweden, on the one hand and international media outlets’ reporting on the Nordic countries on the other. In analysing this cross-fertilizing genre, the article identifies how the welfare state is being repackaged for export along with a set of “progressive values” which are coded as specifically “Nordic.” The article discusses (1) the interaction between outer images and inner visions; (2) the place and significance of the Nordic model, progressive values and the welfare state in today’s Nordic branding; and (3) the possible function of outward competitive identity as a kind of “compensatory imagination” directed inward as well as outward. 相似文献
154.
Rolf Färe Shawna Grosskopf Carl A. PasurkaJr. Ron Shadbegian 《Empirical Economics》2018,54(1):259-285
Morgenstern et al. (J Environ Econ Manag 43:412–436, 2002. doi: 10.1006/jeem.2001.1191) are well-known for its investigation of the employment effects of environmental regulations. However, the cost function specified in that paper is handicapped by its reliance on survey data of the costs of inputs assigned to pollution abatement. In this paper, we specify an input distance function that models the joint production of good and bad outputs. This allows us to measure the relative importance of factors associated with changes in employment without pollution abatement cost data. We operationalize our model using a sample of 80 coal-fired electric power plants from 1995 to 2005. 相似文献
155.
Using a linked employer–employee dataset covering large firms, we present new evidence on British wage inequality trends over the past two decades. Differences between firms in the average wages they paid did not drive these trends. Between 1996 and 2005, greater wage variance within firms accounted for 86% of the total increase in wage variance among employees. In the following decade, wage inequality between firms continued to increase, whereas overall wage dispersion decreased. Approximately all the contribution to inequality dynamics from estimated firm-specific factors, throughout the employee wage distribution, disappears after accounting for the changing occupational content of wages. 相似文献
156.
Carl Lawrence Stanley J. Shapiro Shaheen Lalji 《Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science》1986,14(2):7-16
Reworking published 1981 Census of Canada data, the authors initially present—for all ethnic communities of significant size
(40.000+ nationally)—information on mother tongue, language spoken most often at home, and place of birth. Comparable provincial and
CMA data is then provided. The authors conclude that marketers must supplement Census data with knowledge of such factors
as the relative strength of ethnic affiliations and the drawing power of ethnic media. Custom designed studies of ethnic purchase
and consumption patterns are also considered essential. 相似文献
157.
Multinationals often serve foreign markets by exporting as well as by investing directly in foreign production facilities. We argue that if the multinational competes in an oligopolistic market characterized by strategic complements then there are strategic reasons to use two production facilities—committing to a second source allows the firm to keep average cost low while increasing its marginal cost. The increase in marginal cost softens product market competition resulting in higher profits. We argue that this theory also has implications for the “make or buy” literature in production management and the literature on second sourcing in industrial organization. 相似文献
158.
Review of Industrial Organization - We study how the courts have responded to the 2010 Horizontal Merger Guidelines issued by the U.S. Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission.... 相似文献
159.
160.
Carl Philipson 《Scandinavian actuarial journal》2013,2013(3-4):136-162
Abstract A. Confluent Hypergeometric Functions The theory of such functions will be recapitulated here following a recently published book (Slater, L. J., Confluent Hypergeometric Functions, Cambr. Univ. Press 1960). 相似文献