首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   662篇
  免费   2篇
财政金融   112篇
工业经济   26篇
计划管理   146篇
经济学   166篇
综合类   11篇
运输经济   15篇
旅游经济   27篇
贸易经济   87篇
农业经济   32篇
经济概况   40篇
信息产业经济   2篇
  2021年   7篇
  2020年   6篇
  2019年   7篇
  2018年   13篇
  2017年   14篇
  2016年   11篇
  2015年   11篇
  2014年   11篇
  2013年   87篇
  2012年   15篇
  2011年   20篇
  2010年   16篇
  2009年   22篇
  2008年   21篇
  2007年   17篇
  2006年   17篇
  2005年   17篇
  2004年   14篇
  2003年   16篇
  2002年   7篇
  2001年   18篇
  2000年   11篇
  1999年   12篇
  1998年   12篇
  1997年   12篇
  1996年   22篇
  1995年   18篇
  1994年   6篇
  1993年   9篇
  1992年   4篇
  1991年   8篇
  1990年   6篇
  1989年   7篇
  1988年   8篇
  1987年   6篇
  1986年   5篇
  1985年   15篇
  1984年   9篇
  1983年   4篇
  1982年   13篇
  1981年   18篇
  1980年   14篇
  1979年   12篇
  1978年   9篇
  1977年   7篇
  1976年   6篇
  1975年   10篇
  1974年   7篇
  1973年   5篇
  1971年   4篇
排序方式: 共有664条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
81.
82.
83.
This paper applies Plato’s cave allegory to Enron’s success and downfall. Plato’s famous tale of cave dwellers illustrates the different levels of truth and understanding. These levels include images, the sources of images, and the ultimate reality behind both. The paper first describes these levels of perception as they apply to Plato’s cave dwellers and then provides a brief history of the rise of Enron. Then we apply Plato’s levels of understanding to Enron, showing how the company created its image and presented information to support that image, and how the public eventually emerged from the cave to realize the truth about Enron’s actual accounting practices and financial state, which led to the corporation’s downfall. We find Plato’s allegory both useful in analyzing the relationship between Enron and the public and instructive about the power and moral responsibility of Enron’s executives.  相似文献   
84.
85.
    
In this paper we use the Kumar and Russell [American Economic Review (2002) Vol. 92, pp. 527–548] growth‐accounting procedure to examine cross‐country growth during the 1990s. Using a data set comprising developed, newly industrialized, developing and transitional economies, we decompose the growth of output per worker into components attributable to technological catch‐up, technological change and capital accumulation. In contrast to the study by Kumar and Russell, which concludes that capital deepening is the major force of growth and change in the world income per worker distribution over the 1965–90 period, our analysis shows that, during the 1990s, the major force in the further divergence of the rich and the poor is due to technological change, whereas capital accumulation plays a lesser and opposite role. Finally, although on average we find that transitional economies perform similar to the rest of the world, the procedure is able to discover some interesting patterns within the set of transitional countries.  相似文献   
86.
In 1996 the federal government enacted the Federal Agriculture Improvement and Reform (FAIR) Act, which represented a sweeping change in public policy toward agriculture. This paper examines the impact of the FAIR legislation on farmland values across the U.S. Corn Belt. A representative farm framework is used to determine the impact of FAIR on farmland values. The analysis suggests that marginal production environments are likely to suffer most severely under FAIR, and that a prolonged period of weak commodity prices could engender sharp declines in farmland values.  相似文献   
87.
Using nonparametric, production‐frontier methods, we decompose labor productivity growth into components attributable to technological change (shifts in the world production frontier), technological catch‐up (movements toward or away from the frontier), and physical and human capital accumulation (movements along the frontier). We find that (1) technological change is decidedly nonneutral, (2) productivity growth is driven primarily by physical and human capital accumulation, (3) the increased international dispersion of productivity is explained primarily by physical capital accumulation, and (4) international polarization (the shift from a unimodal to a bimodal distribution) is brought about primarily by efficiency changes (technological catch‐up).  相似文献   
88.
89.
90.
This paper examines the extent to which the concept of vertical coordination in the agro-food sector lends itself to specification or measurement in a manner that is analytically useful. Based on a combination of theory and empirical evidence, it is suggested that vertical organization can be specified as a parameter, variable in degree of control by principal over agent. Such a specification has potential application in analytical models concerned with what gives rise to vertical ties and/or their economic consequences. Drawing principally on the concepts of transactions costs, factor price distortion, and vertical restraint, analytical attention is directed to the economic incentives for, and performance implications of the use of linkages other than spot market transactions for coordinating vertically interdependent stages in the food chain. Research challenges are identified.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号