全文获取类型
收费全文 | 3164篇 |
免费 | 142篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 562篇 |
工业经济 | 227篇 |
计划管理 | 585篇 |
经济学 | 755篇 |
综合类 | 31篇 |
运输经济 | 40篇 |
旅游经济 | 82篇 |
贸易经济 | 606篇 |
农业经济 | 173篇 |
经济概况 | 226篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 18篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 23篇 |
2022年 | 23篇 |
2021年 | 37篇 |
2020年 | 64篇 |
2019年 | 101篇 |
2018年 | 123篇 |
2017年 | 151篇 |
2016年 | 118篇 |
2015年 | 78篇 |
2014年 | 158篇 |
2013年 | 351篇 |
2012年 | 139篇 |
2011年 | 162篇 |
2010年 | 138篇 |
2009年 | 168篇 |
2008年 | 133篇 |
2007年 | 114篇 |
2006年 | 96篇 |
2005年 | 84篇 |
2004年 | 69篇 |
2003年 | 77篇 |
2002年 | 77篇 |
2001年 | 53篇 |
2000年 | 42篇 |
1999年 | 36篇 |
1998年 | 50篇 |
1997年 | 51篇 |
1996年 | 46篇 |
1995年 | 30篇 |
1994年 | 42篇 |
1993年 | 43篇 |
1992年 | 33篇 |
1991年 | 20篇 |
1990年 | 25篇 |
1989年 | 23篇 |
1988年 | 16篇 |
1987年 | 15篇 |
1986年 | 15篇 |
1985年 | 28篇 |
1984年 | 23篇 |
1983年 | 25篇 |
1982年 | 19篇 |
1981年 | 23篇 |
1980年 | 20篇 |
1979年 | 21篇 |
1978年 | 16篇 |
1977年 | 22篇 |
1976年 | 16篇 |
1975年 | 15篇 |
1974年 | 9篇 |
排序方式: 共有3306条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
151.
A dual representation of a technology, e.g., a cost function, may not contain all of the technological information, but it will contain all of the information about input vectors that would be chosen by a cost-minimizing firm. At least this much is clear for deterministic technologies. The main question addressed in this paper is whether the same can be said about stochastic technologies and their dual representations. Despite some pessimism expressed in the stochastic frontier literature on this question, we argue that there is no extra cost imposed in the stochastic case. Thus, the conclusion of this paper is: Just dual it! 相似文献
152.
Daniel J. D’Amico 《Constitutional Political Economy》2018,29(4):424-439
Tullock (in: Rowley (ed) The selected works of Gordon Tullock, Liberty Fund, Indianapolis, pp 399–455, 2005) was skeptical of the presumed economic efficiency of the common law, as adversarialism, apparently inherent to common law procedures, allowed for and was prone to litigiousness. Common law litigations accord to patterns of rent-seeking, as litigants invest ever more resources to assure victory. This paper asks if viable institutional solutions can emerge to resolve the problem Tullock identified. I survey the historical development of the term sycophancy within ancient Greek law as a revealing case study. Though a relatively innocuous pejorative in contemporary parlance, the term’s etymological roots stem from a formative process of ancient legal and institutional change within Athenian Greece. In the wake of specific legal reforms that expanded the scope of governmental authority under Solon (born 638–558 BCE), citizens were given explicit financial incentive to report violators of newly implemented public laws. Thereafter, social stigma surrounding third party legal representation leveraged the term sycophancy in reference to prosecutors motivated by private interests over the public welfare. Forgone social status and eventually formal criminal sanction emerged as offsetting differentials against the incentives of sycophancy. 相似文献
153.
Daniel P. Aldrich 《The Review of Austrian Economics》2018,31(4):457-465
This paper addresses questions raised by Storr, Haeffele-Balch and Grube in their book Community Revival in the Wake of Disaster: Lessons in Local Entrepreneurship (2015). I review the reasons why the book is timely, especially the rising number and costs of disasters globally and the shifting norms on the role of government in disaster management. Social capital serves as a critical engine for resilience to crisis, and I move to demonstrate its importance in the mitigation and recovery stages. Then, I raise a research agenda based on their writings, focusing on building quantitative evidence to match the qualitative data already gathered by the authors. Specifically, I focus on testing claims about the definition and density of entrepreneurs, the role of polycentricity, and the public policy pools that would build entrepreneurial talent in vulnerable communities. 相似文献
154.
Utilizing parametric and nonparametric techniques, we asses the impact of a heretofore relatively unexplored ‘input’ in the educational process, time allocation, on the distribution of academic achievement. Our results indicate that school year length and the number and average duration of classes affect student achievement. However, the effects are not homogeneous – in terms of both direction and magnitude – across the distribution. We find that test scores in the upper tail of the distribution benefit from a shorter school year, while a longer school year increases test scores in the lower tail. Furthermore, test scores in the lower quantiles increase when students have at least eight classes lasting 46–50 min on average, while test scores in the upper quantiles increase when students have seven classes lasting 45 min or less or 51 min or more. 相似文献
155.
156.
Daniel Houser Antoine Bechara Michael Keane Kevin McCabe Vernon Smith 《Games and Economic Behavior》2005,52(2):373
In many research contexts it is useful to group experimental subjects into behavioral “types.” Usually, this is done by pre-specifying a set of candidate decision-making heuristics and assigning each subject to a heuristic in that set. Such approaches might perform poorly when applied to subjects with prefrontal cortex damage, because it can be hard to know what cognitive heuristics such subjects might use. We suggest that the Houser, Keane and McCabe (HKM) robust classification algorithm can be a useful tool in these cases. An important advantage of this classification approach is that it does not require one to specify either the nature or number of subjects' heuristics in advance. Rather, both the number and nature of the heuristics are discerned directly from the data. To illustrate the HKM approach, we draw inferences about heuristics used by subjects in the well-known gambling task [Bechara, A., Damasio, A.R., Damasio, H., Anderson, S., 1994. Insensitivity to future consequences following damage to human prefrontal cortex. Cognition 50, 7–12]. 相似文献
157.
Using nonparametric, production‐frontier methods, we decompose labor productivity growth into components attributable to technological change (shifts in the world production frontier), technological catch‐up (movements toward or away from the frontier), and physical and human capital accumulation (movements along the frontier). We find that (1) technological change is decidedly nonneutral, (2) productivity growth is driven primarily by physical and human capital accumulation, (3) the increased international dispersion of productivity is explained primarily by physical capital accumulation, and (4) international polarization (the shift from a unimodal to a bimodal distribution) is brought about primarily by efficiency changes (technological catch‐up). 相似文献
158.
Which policy objective should a central bank pursue in a monetary union with asymmetric monetary transmission and different rates of inflation? Should it base its decisions on the EU‐wide average of inflation and growth or should it instead focus on (appropriately weighted) national utility losses based on national rates of inflation and growth? We find that a policy which minimises the sum of national utility losses leads to higher average utility if the variability of common shocks is large relative to idiosyncratic demand shocks in the non‐tradables sectors. We draw conclusions for the appropriate weight of common and national objectives in the union. 相似文献
159.
Daniel Oesch 《英国劳资关系杂志》2012,50(2):287-307
This article enquires into the causes of union growth and decline by analysing flows in and out of membership at the level of 70 Swiss union locals over 2006–2008. Gross flows in union membership are much larger than the resulting net changes: annual membership turnover of 10 per cent is a surprisingly constant feature across unions. Net changes in membership are primarily determined by inflows: successful and languishing union locals differ in their entry rates, whereas exit rates are similar. Variance in union locals' entry rates is not usefully explained by the labour market context, but by differences in union strategy. 相似文献
160.
Public good contributions may be affected by the social demand to contribute that is implicit in them. Sensitivity to social pressure predicts behavior in paired dictator and money burning games; the evidence for effects on public good contribution is mixed. 相似文献