The paper analyses the impact of pecuniary externalities in a two-sector economy with an incomplete market structure. Agents in each sector choose their proportion of risky investment. Sector specific risks are assumed to be perfectly negatively correlated. It is shown that the economy is more volatile if risk markets do not exist. With a complete set of risk markets, shocks in one sector will be dampened on the aggregate level. In contrast, when risk markets are absent, pecuniary externalities arising from higher risky investment in one sector can create feedback effects in the other sector. When agents are sufficiently risk averse (their coefficient of relative risk aversion being greater than one), an individually optimal response to the increased riskiness of the price distribution will result in an even riskier price distribution: an increase in risky activity in one sector will lead to an increase in risky activity in the other sector, and this gives multiplier effects.Part of this work has been done while I was visiting assistant professor at the University of Western Ontario, London, Canada.I am grateful to Hans-Werner Sinn for helpful comments. The suggestions of the two referees have contributed to improve the paper considerably. 相似文献
The measurement models for both nationalism and patriotism originally developed by Blank and Schmidt are broadly established. Despite their widespread usage in Germany and beyond, concerns have been voiced about the operationalisation of these nation-related concepts. However, in previous scholarship little attention has been devoted to systematically reviewing the models’ validity. This paper’s major goal is to contribute substantially to research on operationalising national attitudes by thoroughly examining how both nationalism and patriotism are measured and how valid the predominant measurement models really are. By running a confirmatory factor analysis, three measurement models based on the ISSP data of 2003 are replicated and empirically reviewed. By conducting a single-country analysis, the models are tested for the German case, including the evaluation of measurement invariance for both Eastern and Western Germany. Although the selected measurement models yield satisfying results, the paper identifies considerable shortcomings with regard to the way both nationalism and patriotism are empirically approached. It calls for a reconceptualising of the prevailing concept of pride and thus challenges the predominant operationalisation.
Markets are incomplete when the assets available to the agents do not span the space of future contingencies. In that case, competitive equilibria on the markets for assets and commodities fail (generically) to be constrained efficient. Pareto‐superior allocations can be implemented through price/wage rigidities and quantity constraints. However, nominal rigidities are conducive to multiple equilibria, implying endogenous macroeconomic uncertainties that compound the primitive (exogenous) uncertainties. This paper defines a temporary general equilibrium for which there exists a set of equilibria defining an inflation – unemployment locus. Various policy implications are drawn, with relevance to the current crisis. 相似文献
Long run import pass-through is investigated in a partial equilibrium model in the context of a small domestic economy. Contrary to the standard view, it is shown that long run small country pass-through may be incomplete provided three sufficient conditions are met: (i) the foreign producer uses imported inputs, (ii) those inputs are paid for in a neutral currency, and (iii) three-way arbitrage is in operation. The theoretical predictions of.the partial equilibrium model are tested against the results of recent small country empirical studies. The sensitivity of pass through to productivity changes, monopsonistic behaviour, imperfect competition, the timeframe of the firm. and tariff protection are also examined. [F13] 相似文献
An efficiency‐wage model of steady‐state equilibrium with labor‐augmenting technical progress is developed to explore the long‐run relationship between unemployment and growth. The rate of productivity growth is either specified exogenously or determined endogenously. In both cases, we preserve key results of the Shapiro–Stiglitz efficiency‐wage analysis without growth. Our model, however, also yields some striking new results. For instance, an exogenous increase in the growth rate may raise the rate of efficiency‐wage unemployment, and a once‐for‐all rise in the labor force may reduce the unemployment rate in the endogenous‐growth case. 相似文献
Ohne ZusammenfassungSymbole
N
Beschäftigung
-
F (N)
Produktionsfunktion (F>0,F <0)
-
Substitutionselastizität
-
Arbeitsangebot=Arbeitskräftepotential
-
Reallohnsatz
-
w
Nominallohnsatz
-
p
Preisniveau
-
T
Zykluslänge
-
s
Kosten der Erhöhung vonv (gemessen in Einheiten der Lohnsumme/Periode)
-
I
Investition (konstant)
- sp (sw)
Sparquote aus Profiten (Löhnen)
-
Nutzendiskontrate
-
q
Schattenpreis der Erhöhung von 相似文献
Conclusions The results indicated in Table 1 show that incomplete depreciation allowances reinforce the distortions in the equilibrium growth path brought about by an ideal capital income tax. A reduction in the deductible share of economic depreciation, like an increase in the tax rate, raises the current level of consumption, but reduces the steady state levels of consumption and capital per efficiency unit of labour.The reason for these distortions is that the tax law is able to drive wedges both between the rate of time preference and the market rate of interest, and between the latter and the marginal productivity of capital. The first wedge is created through capital income taxation as such and its size is directly related to the tax rate. The second wedge is created by the incomplete deductibility of depreciation. Its size is directly related to the tax rate and inversely to the deductible share of depreciation. For the distortion in the growth path of the economy it is the sum of the two wedges that counts. Therefore it is plausible that incomplete depreciation allowances reinforce the effects of capital income taxation.Knowing the determinants of the two wedges one can easily derive the influence of a tax reform on the marginal productivity of capital, the market rate of interest and the rate of time preference (cf. Table 2). In the short run, the system of these three interest rates is anchored by the marginal productivity of capital, and hence any measure that widens a wedge is translated into a reduction in the rate or those rates below the wedge. In the long run the system is anchored by the rate of time preference and an increase in the width of a wedge is translated into an increase in those rates or that rate above this wedge.The paper was written in association with the Sonderforschungsbereich 5 (Staatliche Allokationspolitik im marktwirtschaftlichen System). 相似文献
Most technological changes can be described as a substitution of one material, process or product for another. Each such substitution, if successful, normally tends to follow an S-shaped (or “logistic”) curve: that is, it starts slowly as initial problems and resistances have to be overcome; then it proceeds more rapidly as the competition between the new and the old technology grows keener and the new technology gains an advantage; and finally, as the market for the new technology approaches saturation, the pace of substitution slows down. Sometimes, when the process is completed, the old technology continues to retain some specialized portion of the total market (i.e., a sub-market) for which it is particularly well adapted. In forecasting the course and speed of the substitution process especially when it has already begun and partially taken place, the simplest approach is to project a function having the appropriate S-shaped curve, using historical data to determine the free parameters of the function. While useful, especially where data are not available for a more sophisticated study, the simple curve-fitting techniques fail to take into account several important factors that affect economic and management decisions on the part of producers and intermediate users (as well as “final” consumers) and thereby influence the course which the substitution process is likely to take. To overcome this limitation, a simulation model has been developed at IR&T which allows some of these factors to be evaluated and incorporated explicitly and quantitatively. The model is described and its application is illustrated in the case of the substitution of plastic for glass in bottles. It is most applicable where the competing technologies are rather precisely defined, where a good deal of current technical and economic data are available, and where an in-depth analysis is desired. Because this particular forecast was made before the sudden precipitous increase in petroleum prices, which upsets the price relationships assumed in the forecast, there is discussion of the vulnerability of forecasts to political and other contra-economic developments. 相似文献
The literature in psychology and behavioral economics offers abundant instances of anomalies to the rational choice paradigm.
One of the most prominent works attempting to reconcile these is Kahneman and Tversky’s Prospect Theory. Its well-known S-shaped
value function accounts for some of the anomalies such as reference dependence, loss aversion, and diminishing sensitivity. Although Prospect Theory describes the manner in which individuals are loss averse, it does not explain why people show loss aversion. This dissertation investigates the factors that affect the cognitive processes behind loss aversion.
We find an anomaly in the S-shaped value function. Specifically, the studies demonstrate that the degree of involvement affects
the slope of the value curve both for atemporal and intertemporal choices. In addition, we also test the relationship between
loss aversion and involvement with varying vividness of outcomes (i.e., when outcomes are related to more versus less vivid
stimuli). Testing the vividness effects further extends and confirms our proposed relationship between involvement and loss
aversion.
The data from several experiments show that there is a difference in the slopes of the value function for low and high involvement
decisions. For low involvement conditions, the value curve has roughly the same steepness for losses as for gains close to
the neutral reference point (i.e., contrary to the diminishing sensitivity characteristic). By contrast, in the high involvement conditions this is not the case: there is a distinct difference in
the slopes of the loss and gain curves. This leads us to propose that different value functions exist for people in the low
and high involvement conditions. This important finding suggests that in cases where people are not highly involved with a
product, they display significantly less loss aversion than predicted by Prospect Theory.
Three experiments investigate the relationship of loss aversion to subjects’ level of involvement in atemporal choice, intertemporal
choice, and differential vividness of stimuli situations, respectively. The first study uses a 2 (involvement: low and high)
by 2 (outcome: gain and loss) between subjects design. The results show that loss aversion significantly attenuates in the
low involvement condition for atemporal choice.
Study two replicates the results of study one in the context of intertemporal choice, where timing of outcomes (now versus
three months) is introduced as another factor.
Finally, the third study manipulates the vividness of outcomes and finds an interaction effect of vividness and involvement
on loss aversion.
Dissertation Committee: Norman Frohlich (Co- Chair), I.H. Asper School of Business, University of Manitoba Edward Bruning (Co- Chair), I.H. Asper
School of Business, University of Manitoba Namita Bhatnagar, I.H. Asper School of Business, University of Manitoba Wayne Simpson,
Department of Economics, University of Manitoba Michael Hu, Department of Marketing, Kent State University 相似文献