全文获取类型
收费全文 | 52篇 |
免费 | 2篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 7篇 |
工业经济 | 1篇 |
计划管理 | 10篇 |
经济学 | 23篇 |
贸易经济 | 10篇 |
经济概况 | 3篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 2篇 |
2021年 | 1篇 |
2020年 | 1篇 |
2018年 | 3篇 |
2016年 | 4篇 |
2015年 | 2篇 |
2014年 | 3篇 |
2013年 | 1篇 |
2012年 | 3篇 |
2010年 | 5篇 |
2009年 | 4篇 |
2008年 | 2篇 |
2007年 | 3篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 2篇 |
2004年 | 1篇 |
2003年 | 2篇 |
2002年 | 3篇 |
2000年 | 1篇 |
1998年 | 1篇 |
1997年 | 1篇 |
1996年 | 2篇 |
1994年 | 2篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1991年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有54条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
21.
The multilinear extension has been shown to be an effective tool for computing the Shapley value of an n-person game. We modify here the method for the multilinear extension to calculate the modified coalition structure value (CS-value) for such games. 相似文献
22.
Eyal Carmel Dana Carmel David Leiser Avia Spivak 《The Journal of consumer affairs》2015,49(3):576-595
Buying a retirement saving plan in Israel involves meeting with an agent whose interests may differ from those of his or her customers. The aim of the present study was to explore the effect of the advice given by the agent, along with that of two further factors: a fair disclosure statement regarding the agent's conflict of interest, and the customer's degree of financial literacy. Two experiments conducted among undergraduate students in Israel showed that customers mostly follow the agent's recommendation, even against their best interest, and despite the presence of a fair disclosure statement. Only participants with high financial literacy, who received a disclosure statement, did examine the alternatives closely and rejected the advice when the recommendation was damaging. We also ruled out the existence of a negative psychological reactance response to a disclosure statement that would work to the detriment of financially literate participants. 相似文献
23.
In a context of constitutional choice of a voting rule, this paper presents an economic analysis of scoring rules that identifies
the golden voting rule under the impartial culture assumption. This golden rule depends on the weights β and (1−β) assigned
to two types of costs: the cost of majority decisiveness (‘tyranny’) and the cost of the ‘erosion’ in the majority principle.
Our first main result establishes that in voting contexts where the number of voters n is typically considerably larger than the number of candidates k, the golden voting rule is the inverse plurality rule for almost any positive β. Irrespective of n and k, the golden voting rule is the inverse plurality rule if β ≥ 1/2 .. This hitherto almost unnoticed rule outperforms any other
scoring rule in eliminating majority decisiveness. The golden voting rule is, however, the plurality rule, the most widely
used voting rule that does not allow even the slightest ‘erosion’ in the majority principle, when β=0. Our second main result
establishes that for sufficiently “small size” voting bodies, the set of potential golden rules consists at most of just three
rules: the plurality rule, the Borda rule and the inverse plurality rule. On the one hand, this finding provides a new rationalization
to the central role the former two rules play in practice and in the voting theory literature. On the other hand, it provides
further support to the inverse plurality rule; not only that it is the golden rule in voting contexts, it also belongs, together
with the plurality rule and the Borda method of counts, to the “exclusive” set of potential golden voting rules in small committees.
We are indebted to Jim Buchanan, Amichai Glazer, Noa Nitzan, Ken Shepsle, and an anonymous
referee for their useful comments. 相似文献
24.
We study the strategic advantages of following rules of thumb that bundle different games together (called rule rationality) when this may be observed by one's opponent. We present a model in which the strategic environment determines which kind of rule rationality is adopted by the players. We apply the model to characterize the induced rules and outcomes in various interesting environments. Finally, we show the close relations between act rationality and “Stackelberg stability” (no player can earn from playing first). 相似文献
25.
The use of sellers' personal photographs online is ubiquitous in sharing economy platforms such as Airbnb. This paper addresses two questions. First, what type of personal photos do hosts choose to post on Airbnb? Second, which of the characteristics of their photos affects their perceived trustworthiness? We answer these questions by building a structural equation model of the relation between the characteristics of the photos and the perceived trustworthiness of the hosts. The antecedents of trust in this model were defined based on insights from psychology regarding first impressions. We found that the hosts' visual characteristics (e.g., gender) as revealed in their online photographs affect their perceived trustworthiness both directly and indirectly via attractiveness. We also found that image characteristics, which are not related directly to the traits of the host in the picture (e.g., photograph quality), play a significant role in trust inference. Interestingly, the hosts' choices of their personal photos suggest that they may not be aware of these effects. 相似文献
26.
Veto power consists of the right of one or more players to unilaterally block decisions but without the ability to unilaterally secure their preferred outcome. Our experiment shows that (i) committees with a veto player take longer to reach decisions (are less efficient) and generate less consensus than without a veto player, (ii) veto power substantially enhances proposer’s power, and (iii) non-veto players are substantially more willing to compromise than veto players. We relate our results to the theoretical literature on the impact of veto power as well as to concerns about the impact of veto power in real-life committees. 相似文献
27.
Fabian Bornhorst Andrea Ichino Oliver Kirchkamp Karl H. Schlag Eyal Winter 《Experimental Economics》2010,13(3):260-283
We run an experiment in which students of different European nationalities are matched in groups of five and repeatedly choose
with whom within their group they want to play a trust game. Participants observe of each other age, gender, nationality and
number of siblings. The region of origin, “North” or “South” is a major determinant of success in the experiment. Participants
tend to trust those they trusted before and who trusted them. We do not find evidence of regional discrimination per se. It
is only the underlying and significant differences in behavior that translate through repeated interactions into differences
in payoffs between the two regions. 相似文献
28.
A Theory of Gradual Coalition Formation 总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3
We study noncooperative multilateral bargaining games, based on underlying TU games, in which coalitions can renegotiate their agreements. We distinguish between models in which players continue to bargain after implementing agreements (reversible actions) and models in which players who implement agreements must leave the game (irreversible actions). We show that renegotiation always results in formation of the grand coalition if actions are reversible, but that the process may otherwise end with smaller coalitions. On the other hand, we show that the grand coalition cannot form in one step if the core of the game is empty, irrespective of the reversibility of actions. 相似文献
29.
We study binary action network games with strategic complementarities. An agent acts if the aggregate social influence of her friends exceeds a transfer levied on the agent by a principal. The principal seeks to maximize her revenue while inducing everyone to act in a unique equilibrium. We characterize optimal transfers showing that agents who are more popular than their friends receive preferential treatment. Our main result is that under mild conditions complete core-periphery networks deliver the highest revenue to the principal. Furthermore, we show that the revenue is higher in networks where links are allocated unequally across agents. Hence, the principal benefits from creating “influentials” by linking well-connected hubs to less popular periphery. 相似文献
30.
The ability to estimate a supplier's marginal cost confers a strategic competitive advantage to the buyer, whether in negotiations with suppliers, in an auction setting, or when an auction is used to initiate the process, which is then followed up with a traditional negotiation. Focusing on electronic reverse auctions characterized by a one‐shot, first‐price, sealed‐bid format, this article proposes an approach for estimating a supplier's marginal cost. Specifically, we suggest a two‐stage model: In the first stage, empirical analysis is used to predict the winning bid. In the second stage, a game‐theory approach is used to refine the outcome of the first stage to provide an estimate of the supplier's marginal cost. To assess the model, we apply it to data from a food and beverages company that carried out electronic auctions to select suppliers for industrial maintenance services. We find that our estimates are very close to those made by the suppliers and compare favorably to the efficient marginal costs determined with the widely used approach of data envelopment analysis. This also implies that after selecting a supplier through an auction, the buyer can enhance follow‐up negotiations with the supplier by contrasting our model's estimates of the marginal costs with the supplier's' inefficiencies detected with the data envelopment analysis. 相似文献