全文获取类型
收费全文 | 30673篇 |
免费 | 330篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 4991篇 |
工业经济 | 1655篇 |
计划管理 | 4972篇 |
经济学 | 7041篇 |
综合类 | 561篇 |
运输经济 | 142篇 |
旅游经济 | 232篇 |
贸易经济 | 6709篇 |
农业经济 | 767篇 |
经济概况 | 3285篇 |
信息产业经济 | 45篇 |
邮电经济 | 603篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 118篇 |
2020年 | 196篇 |
2019年 | 284篇 |
2018年 | 2641篇 |
2017年 | 2431篇 |
2016年 | 1546篇 |
2015年 | 323篇 |
2014年 | 473篇 |
2013年 | 1572篇 |
2012年 | 872篇 |
2011年 | 2277篇 |
2010年 | 2140篇 |
2009年 | 1895篇 |
2008年 | 1835篇 |
2007年 | 2138篇 |
2006年 | 380篇 |
2005年 | 652篇 |
2004年 | 721篇 |
2003年 | 793篇 |
2002年 | 512篇 |
2001年 | 304篇 |
2000年 | 313篇 |
1999年 | 226篇 |
1998年 | 238篇 |
1997年 | 196篇 |
1996年 | 221篇 |
1995年 | 194篇 |
1994年 | 200篇 |
1993年 | 196篇 |
1992年 | 212篇 |
1991年 | 211篇 |
1990年 | 207篇 |
1989年 | 182篇 |
1988年 | 145篇 |
1987年 | 152篇 |
1986年 | 181篇 |
1985年 | 251篇 |
1984年 | 228篇 |
1983年 | 197篇 |
1982年 | 202篇 |
1981年 | 200篇 |
1980年 | 192篇 |
1979年 | 189篇 |
1978年 | 169篇 |
1977年 | 155篇 |
1976年 | 150篇 |
1975年 | 151篇 |
1974年 | 118篇 |
1973年 | 117篇 |
1972年 | 107篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
32.
33.
34.
Richard P. O’Neill Emily Bartholomew Fisher Benjamin F. Hobbs Ross Baldick 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》2008,34(3):220-250
The general design for the real-time electricity market presented in this paper optimizes and prices both real and reactive
power simultaneously in an AC setting, where all assets—generation, load and transmission—are allowed to bid and are financially
settled at the locational price times energy consumed or produced. The result is that transmission lines are compensated for
both capacity and admittance, providing incentives for efficient operation of transmission-related assets such as FACTS devices,
if price-taking behavior is assumed. Losses are incorporated into the design and become an operating cost for transmission.
The market design is shown to be revenue neutral and, under some assumptions, nonconfiscatory.
相似文献
35.
Common sense tells us that the future is an essential element in any strategy. In addition, there is a good deal of literature on scenario planning, which is an important tool in considering the future in terms of strategy. However, in many organizations there is serious resistance to the development of scenarios, and they are not broadly implemented by companies. But even organizations that do not rely heavily on the development of scenarios do, in fact, construct visions to guide their strategies. But it might be asked, what happens when this vision is not consistent with the future? To address this problem, the present article proposes a method for checking the content and consistency of an organization's vision of the future, no matter how it was conceived. The proposed method is grounded on theoretical concepts from the field of future studies, which are described in this article. This study was motivated by the search for developing new ways of improving and using scenario techniques as a method for making strategic decisions. The method was then tested on a company in the field of information technology in order to check its operational feasibility. The test showed that the proposed method is, in fact, operationally feasible and was capable of analyzing the vision of the company being studied, indicating both its shortcomings and points of inconsistency. 相似文献
36.
Extant empirical research has reported nonlinear behavior within arbitrage relationships. In this article, the authors consider potential nonlinear dynamics within FTSE‐100 index and index‐futures. Such nonlinearity can be rationalized by the existence of transactions costs or through the interaction between informed and noise traders. They consider several empirical models designed to capture these alternative dynamics. Their empirical results provide evidence of a stationary basis term, and thus cointegration between index and index‐futures, and the presence of nonlinear dynamics within that relationship. The results further suggest that noise traders typically engage in momentum trading and are more prone to this behavior type when the underlying market is rising. Fundamental, or arbitrage, traders are characterized by heterogeneity, such that there is slow movement between regimes of behavior. In particular, fundamental traders act more quickly in response to small deviations from equilibrium, but are reluctant to act quickly in response to larger mispricings that are exposed to greater noise trader price risk. © 2006 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 26:343–368, 2006 相似文献
37.
Ines Lindner 《Economic Theory》2008,35(3):607-611
We extend Condorcet’s Jury Theorem (Essai sur l’application de l’analyse à la probabilité des décisions rendues à la pluralité
des voix. De l’imprimerie royale, 1785) to weighted voting games with voters of two kinds: a fixed (possibly empty) set of
‘major’ voters with fixed weights, and an ever-increasing number of ‘minor’ voters, whose total weight is also fixed, but
where each individual’s weight becomes negligible. As our main result, we obtain the limiting probability that the jury will
arrive at the correct decision as a function of the competence of the few major players. As in Condorcet’s result the quota
q = 1/2 is found to play a prominent role.
I wish to thank Maurice Koster, Moshé Machover, Guillermo Owen and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. 相似文献
38.
Background risk can influence the performance of insurance markets that must deal with adverse selection when applicants are risk vulnerable, since they are more averse to bearing the insurable risk as a result of their exposures to background risk. We show that background risk always results in a lower deductible for the incentive constrained contract, and that a broader range of markets attains the stable sequential equilibrium cross-subsidized pair of separating contracts. We conclude that background risk always improves the performance of markets for coverage against (insurable) foreground risks that must deal with adverse selection. We also find, however, that these improvements are never sufficient to offset the cost to insureds of bearing the background risk. 相似文献
39.
This paper investigates the nature and behavior of the domestic (local) currency market that existed in Florence (Italy) during the late 14th and early 15th centuries (a.k.a. the Early Renaissance). We find that the extant volatility and microstructure models developed for modern asset markets are able to describe the statistical volatility properties observed for the denaro-florin exchange rate. Volatility is clustered and is related to the bid–ask spread. This supports the notion that, although there are huge social, industrial and technological differences between capitalism then and now, individuals trading financial assets in an organized venue behave in a similar manner. 相似文献
40.