首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   176篇
  免费   4篇
财政金融   46篇
工业经济   9篇
计划管理   24篇
经济学   58篇
运输经济   2篇
旅游经济   1篇
贸易经济   33篇
经济概况   7篇
  2023年   3篇
  2021年   3篇
  2020年   2篇
  2019年   4篇
  2018年   3篇
  2017年   3篇
  2016年   4篇
  2015年   5篇
  2014年   7篇
  2013年   15篇
  2012年   9篇
  2011年   14篇
  2010年   12篇
  2009年   5篇
  2008年   10篇
  2007年   2篇
  2006年   2篇
  2005年   7篇
  2004年   2篇
  2003年   5篇
  2002年   3篇
  2001年   6篇
  2000年   4篇
  1999年   4篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   4篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1992年   2篇
  1991年   2篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1988年   1篇
  1987年   2篇
  1984年   1篇
  1983年   1篇
  1982年   6篇
  1981年   1篇
  1980年   2篇
  1976年   2篇
  1974年   1篇
  1973年   2篇
  1970年   1篇
  1967年   2篇
  1966年   2篇
  1962年   2篇
  1958年   1篇
  1940年   1篇
  1903年   1篇
排序方式: 共有180条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
91.
Catalonia was the only Mediterranean region among the early followers of the British industrial revolution. The roots of this process can be traced back to the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries when the Catalan economy became integrated into international trade, and a successful printed calico industry concentrated in the city of Barcelona. Although the factory system was largely adopted by the cotton industry in the 1840s, the diffusion of the spinning jenny in Catalonia had occurred earlier, in the 1790s. In line with Allen, this article explores whether relative factor prices played a role in the widespread adoption of the spinning jenny in Catalonia. First, series of real wages in Barcelona are supplied for the period 1500–1808. Second, the prices of labour and capital are compared and the potential profitability of the adoption of the spinning jenny is analysed. Findings show that although Catalonia was not a high wage economy in the way that Britain was in the second half of the eighteenth century, evidence from the cotton spinning sector confirms the relevance of relative factor prices in the adoption of new technology. Within the booming cotton sector after the 1780s, high wages created strong incentives for the adoption of the labour‐saving spinning jenny.  相似文献   
92.
Because of the scarcity of data, there are few quantitative analyses dealing with clandestine markets, despite their prime importance during wartime. This article exploits a unique database of daily prices of gold coins traded in occupied Paris in order to gain insights into the price formation on such a market. First, using data from Switzerland, we show that arbitrage took place, despite the costs and risks involved, and led to a gradual (but incomplete) convergence of gold prices. Furthermore, a study of price seasonality reveals that less strict borders controls during the weekends made the volatility of returns higher at the start of the following week. Second, on the basis of an event study, we provide evidence that laws related to black markets did not have a significant impact on the gold price, except for the most severe law passed on 8 June 1943 which greatly increased the sentences for involvement. Finally, we assess whether the so‐called coin premiums existed on this clandestine market, and show that the large price variations for one gram of fine gold contained in different coins were due to market participants’ preferences for specific gold coins.  相似文献   
93.
94.
95.
96.
The absence of clear convergence in incomes per capita and welfare between the North and the South, even in the face of spectacular growth rates in GDP in the emerging South, might be due to a terms of trade deterioration resulting from an expansion of production in the South which depresses the product’s price on world markets. This may originate from a “technical catch up” and also from a “demographic dividend” in the South relative to an ageing North. This article illustrates that some South-South trade diversification might mitigate the terms of trade deterioration and increase welfare gains in the South. We use a multicountry overlapping-generation general equilibrium model to simulate the magnitude of the terms of trade effect due to a demographic dividend in Turkey, and show that some trade diversification away from EU toward the South is a welfare improving policy for Turkey.  相似文献   
97.
Many structural models specify the default barrier, but few have explored its empirical significance and determinants. The effect of liquidity shortage is not well measured, nor is the effect of strategic default well identified. We use the maximum likelihood (ML) approach to estimate the default barrier model and the Merton-KMV model using market values of equities in a sample of 762 public industrial firms. The estimated barrier is below leverage in our sample. The default probability from the two structural models provides similar in-sample fits, but the default barrier framework achieves better out-of-sample forecasts. Our analysis also focuses on the factors that influence the level of the implied default barrier when leverage is endogenous, and shows that endogenous leverage is not the only determinant of the default barrier as predicted by the standard structural credit model. The implied default threshold is positively related to financing costs, and negatively related to liquidity, asset volatility, and firm size. Three strategic default variables (liquidation costs, renegotiation frictions and equity holders’ bargaining power) increase the implied default barrier level. This evidence supports strategic default models.  相似文献   
98.
This note determines a rule to share a surplus gained when two countries or regions agree to coordinate their policies to reduce downstream pollution. An intertemporal decomposition scheme for the total side payment is proposed. This scheme has the following individual rationality property: in each subgame that starts along the cooperative trajectory, one country is guaranteed to receive a higher payoff in the cooperative solution than in the disagreement solution. For this country another notion of individual rationality obtains: this country will at any instant of time during the play of the game receive a higher payoff in the cooperative solution than in the disagreement solution.  相似文献   
99.
100.
This paper documents a robust empirical regularity: in the long-run, higher trade openness is associated with a lower structural rate of unemployment. We establish this fact using: (i) panel data from 20 OECD countries, (ii) cross-sectional data on a larger set of countries. The time structure of the panel data allows us to control for unobserved heterogeneity, whereas cross-sectional data make it possible to instrument openness by its geographical component. In both setups, we purge the data of business cycle effects, include a host of institutional and geographical variables, and control for within-country trade. Our main finding is robust to various definitions of unemployment rates and openness measures. Our benchmark specification suggests that a 10 percentage point increase in total trade openness reduces aggregate unemployment by about three quarters of one percentage point.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号