全文获取类型
收费全文 | 176篇 |
免费 | 4篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 46篇 |
工业经济 | 9篇 |
计划管理 | 24篇 |
经济学 | 58篇 |
运输经济 | 2篇 |
旅游经济 | 1篇 |
贸易经济 | 33篇 |
经济概况 | 7篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 3篇 |
2021年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 2篇 |
2019年 | 4篇 |
2018年 | 3篇 |
2017年 | 3篇 |
2016年 | 4篇 |
2015年 | 5篇 |
2014年 | 7篇 |
2013年 | 15篇 |
2012年 | 9篇 |
2011年 | 14篇 |
2010年 | 12篇 |
2009年 | 5篇 |
2008年 | 10篇 |
2007年 | 2篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 7篇 |
2004年 | 2篇 |
2003年 | 5篇 |
2002年 | 3篇 |
2001年 | 6篇 |
2000年 | 4篇 |
1999年 | 4篇 |
1998年 | 2篇 |
1997年 | 4篇 |
1996年 | 2篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1992年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 2篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1987年 | 2篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 1篇 |
1982年 | 6篇 |
1981年 | 1篇 |
1980年 | 2篇 |
1976年 | 2篇 |
1974年 | 1篇 |
1973年 | 2篇 |
1970年 | 1篇 |
1967年 | 2篇 |
1966年 | 2篇 |
1962年 | 2篇 |
1958年 | 1篇 |
1940年 | 1篇 |
1903年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有180条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
91.
Catalonia was the only Mediterranean region among the early followers of the British industrial revolution. The roots of this process can be traced back to the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries when the Catalan economy became integrated into international trade, and a successful printed calico industry concentrated in the city of Barcelona. Although the factory system was largely adopted by the cotton industry in the 1840s, the diffusion of the spinning jenny in Catalonia had occurred earlier, in the 1790s. In line with Allen, this article explores whether relative factor prices played a role in the widespread adoption of the spinning jenny in Catalonia. First, series of real wages in Barcelona are supplied for the period 1500–1808. Second, the prices of labour and capital are compared and the potential profitability of the adoption of the spinning jenny is analysed. Findings show that although Catalonia was not a high wage economy in the way that Britain was in the second half of the eighteenth century, evidence from the cotton spinning sector confirms the relevance of relative factor prices in the adoption of new technology. Within the booming cotton sector after the 1780s, high wages created strong incentives for the adoption of the labour‐saving spinning jenny. 相似文献
92.
Georges Gallais‐Hamonno Thi‐Hong‐Van Hoang Kim Oosterlinck 《The Economic history review》2019,72(3):1048-1072
Because of the scarcity of data, there are few quantitative analyses dealing with clandestine markets, despite their prime importance during wartime. This article exploits a unique database of daily prices of gold coins traded in occupied Paris in order to gain insights into the price formation on such a market. First, using data from Switzerland, we show that arbitrage took place, despite the costs and risks involved, and led to a gradual (but incomplete) convergence of gold prices. Furthermore, a study of price seasonality reveals that less strict borders controls during the weekends made the volatility of returns higher at the start of the following week. Second, on the basis of an event study, we provide evidence that laws related to black markets did not have a significant impact on the gold price, except for the most severe law passed on 8 June 1943 which greatly increased the sentences for involvement. Finally, we assess whether the so‐called coin premiums existed on this clandestine market, and show that the large price variations for one gram of fine gold contained in different coins were due to market participants’ preferences for specific gold coins. 相似文献
93.
94.
95.
Georges de Leener 《De Economist》1903,52(1):467-488
96.
The absence of clear convergence in incomes per capita and welfare between the North and the South, even in the face of spectacular growth rates in GDP in the emerging South, might be due to a terms of trade deterioration resulting from an expansion of production in the South which depresses the product’s price on world markets. This may originate from a “technical catch up” and also from a “demographic dividend” in the South relative to an ageing North. This article illustrates that some South-South trade diversification might mitigate the terms of trade deterioration and increase welfare gains in the South. We use a multicountry overlapping-generation general equilibrium model to simulate the magnitude of the terms of trade effect due to a demographic dividend in Turkey, and show that some trade diversification away from EU toward the South is a welfare improving policy for Turkey. 相似文献
97.
Many structural models specify the default barrier, but few have explored its empirical significance and determinants. The effect of liquidity shortage is not well measured, nor is the effect of strategic default well identified. We use the maximum likelihood (ML) approach to estimate the default barrier model and the Merton-KMV model using market values of equities in a sample of 762 public industrial firms. The estimated barrier is below leverage in our sample. The default probability from the two structural models provides similar in-sample fits, but the default barrier framework achieves better out-of-sample forecasts. Our analysis also focuses on the factors that influence the level of the implied default barrier when leverage is endogenous, and shows that endogenous leverage is not the only determinant of the default barrier as predicted by the standard structural credit model. The implied default threshold is positively related to financing costs, and negatively related to liquidity, asset volatility, and firm size. Three strategic default variables (liquidation costs, renegotiation frictions and equity holders’ bargaining power) increase the implied default barrier level. This evidence supports strategic default models. 相似文献
98.
This note determines a rule to share a surplus gained when two countries or regions agree to coordinate their policies to reduce downstream pollution. An intertemporal decomposition scheme for the total side payment is proposed. This scheme has the following individual rationality property: in each subgame that starts along the cooperative trajectory, one country is guaranteed to receive a higher payoff in the cooperative solution than in the disagreement solution. For this country another notion of individual rationality obtains: this country will at any instant of time during the play of the game receive a higher payoff in the cooperative solution than in the disagreement solution. 相似文献
99.
100.
This paper documents a robust empirical regularity: in the long-run, higher trade openness is associated with a lower structural rate of unemployment. We establish this fact using: (i) panel data from 20 OECD countries, (ii) cross-sectional data on a larger set of countries. The time structure of the panel data allows us to control for unobserved heterogeneity, whereas cross-sectional data make it possible to instrument openness by its geographical component. In both setups, we purge the data of business cycle effects, include a host of institutional and geographical variables, and control for within-country trade. Our main finding is robust to various definitions of unemployment rates and openness measures. Our benchmark specification suggests that a 10 percentage point increase in total trade openness reduces aggregate unemployment by about three quarters of one percentage point. 相似文献