全文获取类型
收费全文 | 118篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 19篇 |
工业经济 | 2篇 |
计划管理 | 10篇 |
经济学 | 53篇 |
综合类 | 1篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
贸易经济 | 20篇 |
农业经济 | 6篇 |
经济概况 | 6篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 3篇 |
2022年 | 1篇 |
2021年 | 4篇 |
2020年 | 5篇 |
2019年 | 8篇 |
2018年 | 6篇 |
2017年 | 12篇 |
2016年 | 7篇 |
2015年 | 6篇 |
2014年 | 8篇 |
2013年 | 7篇 |
2012年 | 9篇 |
2011年 | 4篇 |
2010年 | 5篇 |
2009年 | 7篇 |
2008年 | 4篇 |
2007年 | 4篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 1篇 |
2004年 | 2篇 |
2003年 | 3篇 |
2002年 | 3篇 |
2001年 | 1篇 |
2000年 | 2篇 |
1997年 | 1篇 |
1991年 | 2篇 |
1978年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有118条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
Much research has suggested that independent boards of directors are more effective in reducing agency costs and improving firm governance. How they influence innovation is less clear. Relying on regulatory changes, we show that firms that transition to independent boards focus on more crowded and familiar areas of technology. They patent and claim more and receive more total future citations to their patents. However, the citation increase comes mainly from incremental patents in the middle of the citation distribution; the numbers of uncited and highly cited patents—arguably associated with riskier innovation strategies—do not change significantly. 相似文献
32.
Gustavo Ghidini 《Journal of Consumer Policy》1978,2(4):316-325
The present paper gives a critical survey of the main trends in the correction of unfair advertising under Italian law. From the viewpoint of consumer interest, such trends appear unsatisfactory in so far as they refer to an average consumer standard, a concept that results in too limited legal intervention. Aside from this, consumer associations and groups are still barred from access to legal action under unfair competition law. Thus, the most adequate legal model to date, seems to be the one founded on the administrative authorization of advertising, which embodies a preventive control of advertisements. Discussed also are self-regulation norms and practices, whose recent improvement is nevertheless insufficient to overcome structural defects.
Gustavo Ghidini is Professor of Law at the University of Modena, Italy. His address is: Via C. Battisti 8, I-20122 Milan, Italy. In 1973 he became a founder of the Comitato Difesa Consumatori, an association now member of Bureau Européen des Unions de Consommateurs (B. E. U. C.). 相似文献
Probleme des Verbraucherschutzes gegenüber unlauterer Werbung im italienischen Recht
Zusammenfassung In Italien gibt es kein auf die Belange des Verbraucherschutzes zugeschnittenes Werberecht. Täuschende und irreführende Werbeangaben gegenüber Verbrauchern werden unter bestimmten Umständen als »unlauterer Wettbewerb« behandelt. Das italienische Recht regelt dabei nur solche Werbeaussagen, die ganz bestimmte Tatsachen enthalten, womit also Übertreibungen auch täuschenden Inhalts keiner Rechtskontrolle unterliegen. Umgekehrt fehlt ein Grundsatz, daß die Werbung ein Mindestmaß an Informationen enthalten muß; das Unterlassen von Angaben wird nicht als Täuschung angesehen. Die Irreführung wird nicht an den von einer Werbebotschaft betroffenen Verbrauchern gemessen, sondern an einem fiktiven Maßstab des »Durchschnittsverbrauchers«.Der Autor kritisiert diese Voraussetzungen des Irreführungsverbotes im italienischen Recht und weist auf Widersprüche in den Begründungszusammenhängen, aber auch auf neue Tendenzen hin. Das Werbestrafrecht kennt in einigen Bereichen strengere Maßstäbe.Die Rechtsdurchsetzung im italienischen Recht weist viele Lücken auf. So haben Verbraucherverbände kein Klagerecht. Eine präventive Werbekontrolle findet praktisch nicht statt. Es sollte deshalb überlegt werden, die verwaltungsrechtliche Kontrolle der Werbung zu erweitern.Die inzwischen auch in Italien ausgebaute Werbeselbstkontrolle befriedigt vom Verbraucherstandpunkt aus nicht. Die Selbstbeschränkungsabkommen sind rechtlich nicht verbindlich. Nur als Ergänzung, nicht aber als Ersatz einer staatlichen Werbekontrolle erscheinen sie sinnvoll.
Gustavo Ghidini is Professor of Law at the University of Modena, Italy. His address is: Via C. Battisti 8, I-20122 Milan, Italy. In 1973 he became a founder of the Comitato Difesa Consumatori, an association now member of Bureau Européen des Unions de Consommateurs (B. E. U. C.). 相似文献
33.
Douglas Alcantara Alencar Frederico G. Jayme Jr. Gustavo Britto 《Journal of post Keynesian economics》2018,41(3):455-477
This research analyzes, from a post Kaleckian perspective, the interactions among the aggregate demand, the real exchange rate, productivity, and real wages in the Brazilian economy from 1960 to 2011. It adopts the longstanding perspective that demand is the driver of capital accumulation and economic growth. The research comprises the following steps: (a) a critical assessment of the growth regime literature, with a particular emphasis on issues related to productivity and the real exchange rate; (b) understanding the relationship between the real exchange rate and the productivity and growth regimes; (c) proposing a theoretical model that relates the real exchange rate, productivity, and the growth regime; and (d) an empirical test of the interaction between the real exchange rate, productivity, and the growth regime. Theoretically the study develops a model showing the interactions between the aggregate demand, the real exchange rate, productivity, and real wages. Furthermore, this research attempts to address the lack of theoretical and empirical studies about the relationship between the aggregate demand, the real exchange rate, productivity and real wages. 相似文献
34.
This paper analyzes the relationship between social networks and the probability of finding a job. We explore geographic closeness as the social interaction to explain the job search function. Using data from Colombia in 2009, we calculate how neighborhoods have an effect on the channel used to find a job (social network versus no social network). In addition, we study how wage premium relates to using a social network in finding a job, exploring the inequality that can arise using a different job search method. Our results show that neighborhood affects the individual's job search method and that referred workers earn less at the bottom of the wage distribution with respect to non‐referred workers. Colombia presents persistent high levels of informality and inequality with the existence of spatial clusters that impose important social and economic costs with strong informational asymmetries on the job market. 相似文献
35.
Gustavo F. Velasco 《American journal of economics and sociology》2018,77(1):95-123
The second half of the 19th century represented an era of great territorial expansion in almost all the countries of “recent settlement.” In Canada, Winnipeg, the capital of the Province of Manitoba, went from a small hamlet located at the confluence of the Assiniboine and Red Rivers to become the third largest Canadian city at the turn of the century. I argue that the development of a real estate market and the organization of the local political institutions in Winnipeg were interconnected mechanisms that the emerging business elite used to obtain political and economic power during the years of city organization (1870–1885). The disputes over land ownership and the uncertain distribution of land titles among parties related by business and family ties showed how individuals exploited the weakness of the state to secure personal benefits. In this era, old settlers, newcomers, speculators, and business representatives of central Canada and British firms, acting alone or in partnership, attempted to obtain political control of a city in its making and to acquire power and economic benefits through the commodification of urban land. After a period of corruption and mismanagement, a new group organized within the Board of Trade obtained political control of the city and initiated a new cycle of political stability. 相似文献
36.
Gustavo Lannelongue Oscar Gonzalez-Benito Javier Gonzalez-Benito 《Journal of Business Ethics》2014,124(1):135-147
The aim of this research is to ascertain whether a firm’s environmental motivations may help to predict how complete or incomplete its environmental management will be, understanding incomplete management to be that which neglects one or more of the three keys aspects of such management, namely, monitoring, action and results. We specifically posit that while motivations based on the search for legitimation lead to more incomplete styles of environmental management, competitive motivations entail a more complete management. The analyses conducted with a sample of 1,902 plants provide empirical evidence in favour of such reasoning. The contribution this research makes, therefore, is not restricted solely to showing the effect motivations have on the environmental performance of organisations, as it also introduces a new dimension of environmental management—the degree of completeness, which needs to be considered when understanding and evaluating this effect. 相似文献
37.
This article analyzes the effects of differential tax treatment of married and single individuals in the United States on marriage formation and composition, divorce, and labor supply. We develop a marriage‐market model with search frictions and heterogeneous agents that is sufficiently rich to capture key elements of the problem under consideration. We then calibrate the model and use it to evaluate the quantitative effects of several tax reforms aimed at making the tax law neutral with respect to marital status. We find that these reforms (i) systematically increase the labor supply of married females, with changes ranging from 0.3 to 10.1 percent; (ii) have substantial effects on the correlation of spouses’ incomes, which changes from 0.2 to values between 0.185 and 0.334; (iii) can lead to either an increase or decrease in the fraction of people married, with changes that range from ?0.6 to 2.4 percent. 相似文献
38.
Maria Aristizabal‐Ramirez Maria Camila Botero‐Franco Gustavo Canavire‐Bacarreza 《Review of Development Economics》2017,21(3):475-496
Using firm‐level data from 2006 to 2013 for a set of developing countries, we examine the effects of financial development on innovation. Financial development boosts innovation by improving resource allocation and investment in strategic sectors as well as facilitating technology to promote growth. Using binary response models and instrumental variable techniques to correct for endogeneity, we find robust but puzzling results. Contrary to most of the existing literature, financial development has a negative effect on the probability of a firm to innovate in developing countries. This effect is conditional on firm size, and only larger firms benefit from financial development. These results are robust to different measures of financial development and econometric specifications. We argue that this is a result of the design of the financial system in regard to the lack of capital and institutional system. Consequently, developing countries should first generate appropriate institutional conditions if they want financial development to spur growth through innovation. 相似文献
39.
We develop a span-of-control model where managerial skills are endogenous and the outcome of investments over the life cycle of managers. We calibrate this model to U.S. plant-size data to quantify the effects of distortions that are correlated with the size of production units, and how these effects are amplified by managerial investments. We find a quantitatively important role for managerial investments. Distortions that consist of a tax rate of 20% on the top 50% managers reduce steady-state output by about 14.6% in our benchmark model. When skills are exogenous the reduction is about 9.2%. 相似文献
40.
Many policies – on the delivery of inputs or on marketing systems, credit, or extension – influence the potential utilization of new technologies. Through 'farm-based policy analysis' it is possible to use data generated in on-farm research (OFR) to identify policy constraints to the use of new technologies, and to effectively communicate that information to policy makers. This paper describes a tentative framework for farm-based policy analysis and suggests a sequence of five steps for the analysis: (1) identify the policy-induced constraints; (2) determine the rationale behind the policy; (3) identify the decision makers to whom the results should be communicated; (4) identify solutions or policy options; and (5) communicate results to decision makers. A case of farm-based policy analysis from Haiti illustrates the concepts and methods described in the first part of the paper. On-farm experiments in Les Cayes, Haiti, confirmed a response to nitrogen in maize, but adoption of the recommended practice and consequent gains in productivity and income were constrained by the scarcity of urea in the local market. An analysis of local supply and potential local demand for urea and the potential benefits of urea application was conducted, and results communicated to two target groups of decision makers: representatives of the Ministry of Agriculture responsible for fertilizer distribution policy, and representatives of private fertilizer enterprises. These groups responded by making larger supplies of urea available to local farmers. Adoption of the fertilizer recommendation and urea sales increased. The case demonstrates the potential value of farm-based policy analysis building upon data from OFR. 相似文献