全文获取类型
收费全文 | 454篇 |
免费 | 11篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 68篇 |
工业经济 | 34篇 |
计划管理 | 88篇 |
经济学 | 120篇 |
综合类 | 6篇 |
运输经济 | 12篇 |
旅游经济 | 9篇 |
贸易经济 | 84篇 |
农业经济 | 17篇 |
经济概况 | 27篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 4篇 |
2020年 | 10篇 |
2019年 | 8篇 |
2018年 | 11篇 |
2017年 | 11篇 |
2016年 | 11篇 |
2015年 | 9篇 |
2014年 | 10篇 |
2013年 | 83篇 |
2012年 | 12篇 |
2011年 | 24篇 |
2010年 | 11篇 |
2009年 | 19篇 |
2008年 | 13篇 |
2007年 | 14篇 |
2006年 | 6篇 |
2005年 | 15篇 |
2004年 | 10篇 |
2003年 | 15篇 |
2002年 | 12篇 |
2001年 | 14篇 |
2000年 | 9篇 |
1999年 | 9篇 |
1998年 | 7篇 |
1997年 | 13篇 |
1996年 | 3篇 |
1995年 | 11篇 |
1994年 | 4篇 |
1993年 | 7篇 |
1992年 | 4篇 |
1991年 | 7篇 |
1990年 | 3篇 |
1989年 | 4篇 |
1988年 | 3篇 |
1987年 | 2篇 |
1986年 | 7篇 |
1985年 | 8篇 |
1984年 | 5篇 |
1983年 | 6篇 |
1982年 | 7篇 |
1980年 | 4篇 |
1979年 | 3篇 |
1978年 | 3篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1976年 | 3篇 |
1975年 | 3篇 |
1974年 | 2篇 |
1973年 | 1篇 |
1971年 | 1篇 |
1970年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有465条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
451.
Policymakers around the world are considering whether to invest in putting information and communication technology (ICT) in schools, and how. While educational impact is likely to be the primary objective, such investments can also affect residential adoption and adult utilization of ICT in the communities, thereby reducing the digital divide. Using a census survey of Thailand for a time when ICT was available in roughly half of the nation’s schools, this study employs logistic regression and propensity score matching (PSM) to show that placing ICT in schools does have significant spill-over effects outside schools. This effect is larger for ICT in primary schools than secondary schools, and larger in schools with both Internet and computers than schools with just computers. The effects are observed in households of all incomes and educational levels. Considering these spill-over effects when allocating resources should lead to greater welfare gains for the amount of resources spent. The study also finds that there is a sizable portion of the adult population that chooses not to use ICT even after adopting this ICT in their households for their children, thereby eliminating any barriers to use related to cost and convenience. For this group, policy-makers should seek ways to decrease other impediments to ICT use, such as increasing ICT literacy through training. 相似文献
452.
Dale?W.?Jorgenson Mun?S.?HoEmail author Jon?D.?Samuels 《Journal of Productivity Analysis》2011,36(2):159-175
The rapid productivity growth in the US during the Information Age, prior to the dot-com bust in 2000, and the large contribution
of the IT producing sector, is well known. Less known are the sources of the surprisingly rapid TFP growth during the slow
growth period after 2000. We construct an account of US economic growth by aggregating over detailed industries using a new
data set based on the NAICS classification. We find that, post 2000, TFP originating from the IT-Producing sector decelerated
relative to the IT boom, but still accounted for 40% of aggregate productivity growth. This deceleration was counterbalanced
by the contribution from IT-Using sectors, which buoyed aggregate TFP growth to almost the same rate as the 1995–2000 period.
For aggregate GDP, the contributions to the growth rate of 2.8% during 2000–2007 were: capital input (1.7% points), labor
input (0.4) and TFP (0.7). 相似文献
453.
Jon Landeta Jon Barrutia Jon Hoyos 《International Journal of Human Resource Management》2013,24(1):164-185
What makes companies give their support to Continuous Management Training (CMT) and why, on occasion, do they block its progress? If a company thinks its managers might leave in the near future, would there be reasons for it to provide continuous training of these professionals? Do companies interpret all likely resignations in the same way? We attempt to provide an answer to these questions, by analysing the behaviour of companies' vis-à-vis continuous management training in terms of their expectations of the appropriability of the benefits that stem from such training. Appropriability is in turn assessed with regard to firms' expectations that their managers will leave their organisation without it having had the chance to recover the outlay invested in training. The analysis of business behaviour also demands an understanding of how these turnover expectations are produced and, more specifically, of the variables on which turnover expectations depend or might depend. The empirical study we carried out with over 300 Spanish companies revealed that company projections for voluntary turnover of management employees are positively connected with earlier experiences of turnover, with markets prone to change, and with business risk situations, and negatively associated with developed social management networks, satisfied managers and their degree of specificity in relation to the company. Nevertheless, no significant relationship was observed between expected turnover and the intensity of continuous management training. In general, companies make their management training investment decisions independently of the overall turnover expectations they might have. Different causes might exist for this absence of a relationship, centred in particular on the need for management training and an associated sense of urgency, which takes precedence over the risk of not recovering the investment when the business decision is taken, and on the nature of the management turnover perceived by the company, which is more complex than a strictly economic one. 相似文献
454.
International Advances in Economic Research - A sizable literature related to the efficiency of the U.S. hospital sector has been produced over the past 30 years. Much of this research is... 相似文献
455.
Scenario Analysis of Chinese Passenger Vehicle Growth 总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2
This article reports on a simulation and scenario analysis of Chinese passenger vehicle growth and resulting energy demand and CO2 emissions. The model includes provincial level logistic growth functions with saturation levels representative of neighboring Asian economies, income growth measured in international dollars, and both estimated and literature-based income elasticities. Scenarios explore variation in key parameters, including income and population growth rates, elasticity income ranges, fuel economy, and vehicle saturation. Countrywide base case results estimate growth from 4.22 to 54.33 passenger vehicles per thousand people from 1995 to 2025. Resulting passenger vehicle oil demands and CO2 emissions increase nearly 17-fold. 相似文献
456.
Jon X. Eguia 《Economic Theory》2012,49(3):549-570
Members of an assembly that chooses policies on a series of multidimensional ideological issues have incentives to coalesce and coordinate their votes, forming political parties. If an agent has an advantage to organize a party at a lower cost, a unique party forms and the policy outcome moves away from the Condorcet winning policy, to the benefit of party members. If all agents have the same opportunities to coalesce into parties, at least two parties form. The results are robust to the consideration of an endogenous agenda and to generalizations of the distribution of preferences. 相似文献
457.
Jon D. Wisman 《Review of Political Economy》2014,26(3):372-391
The financial crisis of 1929 that triggered the Great Depression has been endlessly studied. Still there is little consensus regarding what caused it. This article claims that wage stagnation and exploding inequality fueled three dynamics that set the stage for a financial crisis. First, consumption was constrained by the smaller share of total income accruing to workers, thereby restricting investment opportunities in the real economy. Flush with greater income and wealth, the elite flooded financial markets with credit, helping keep interest rates low and encouraging the creation of new credit instruments, some of which recycled the rich's surplus assets as debt to those less well off. Second, greater inequality pressured households to find ways to consume more in order to maintain their relative social status, resulting in reduced household saving, greater household debt, and possibly longer work hours. Third, as the rich took larger shares of income and wealth, they gained relatively more command over everything, including ideology. Reducing taxes on the rich, favoring business over labor, and failing to regulate newly evolving credit instruments flowed out of this ideology. 相似文献
458.
459.
Jon Strand 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2007,38(4):527-543
I derive values of marginal changes in a public good for two-person households, measured alternatively by household member
i’s willingness to pay (WTP) for the good on behalf of the household, WTP
i
(H), or by the sum of individual WTP values across family members, WTP(C). Households are assumed to allocate their resources in efficient Nash bargains over private and common household goods.
WTP
i
(H) is then defined by trade-offs between the public good and the household good, and WTP(C) by trade-offs of between the public good and private goods. WTP
i
(H) is found to be higher (lower) than WTP(C) when member i has a relatively high (low) marginal valuation of the public good, but tends on average to equal WTP(C). As a consequence, individuals tend to represent households correctly on average when questioned about the household’s WTP
for a public good, even when they are purely selfish and answer truthfully. Adding all members’ WTP answers on behalf of the
household then leads to double counting. Pure and paternalistic altruism (the latter attached to consumption of the public
good) move each member’s WTP on behalf of the household closer to the true sum of individual WTP, but only paternalistic altruism
raises this sum.
相似文献
460.
The effects of advertising on consumption of alcoholic beverages in the US are analysed. The goal is to obtain evidence on the importance of advertising at the level of beverage demand(beer, wine, spirits) and for total consumption of alcohol (per capita gallons of ethanol). A three-equation conditional demand system is estimated that includes own- and cros-beverage advertising as explanatory variables. Four models of the differential demand system are estimated, including the Rotterdam, AID, CBS, and NBR models, using annual US data for the period 1964-90 on beverage consumption, prices, expednitures, and real advertising. Estimates are obtained of the complete matrix of own- and cross-elascities for each beverage’ price and advertising. At the beverage level, the results indicate a positive butr very small effect of advertising on beverage consumption, with most of the impact due to wine advertising and non due to beer advertising. There is no efect of advertising in the composite demand function for alcohol. Hence, the results from system-wide modelling suggest that alcohol advertising serves to reallocate brand sales, with no effect on total ethanol consumption and very small effects on beverage consumption. 相似文献