全文获取类型
收费全文 | 268篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 26篇 |
工业经济 | 6篇 |
计划管理 | 41篇 |
经济学 | 121篇 |
运输经济 | 1篇 |
旅游经济 | 5篇 |
贸易经济 | 44篇 |
农业经济 | 5篇 |
经济概况 | 13篇 |
邮电经济 | 6篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 3篇 |
2020年 | 5篇 |
2019年 | 7篇 |
2018年 | 11篇 |
2017年 | 6篇 |
2016年 | 12篇 |
2014年 | 10篇 |
2013年 | 23篇 |
2012年 | 5篇 |
2011年 | 8篇 |
2010年 | 3篇 |
2009年 | 8篇 |
2008年 | 10篇 |
2007年 | 7篇 |
2006年 | 7篇 |
2005年 | 11篇 |
2004年 | 5篇 |
2003年 | 5篇 |
2002年 | 5篇 |
2001年 | 3篇 |
2000年 | 6篇 |
1999年 | 3篇 |
1998年 | 4篇 |
1997年 | 3篇 |
1996年 | 3篇 |
1995年 | 2篇 |
1994年 | 5篇 |
1993年 | 5篇 |
1992年 | 4篇 |
1991年 | 3篇 |
1990年 | 3篇 |
1989年 | 2篇 |
1986年 | 3篇 |
1985年 | 9篇 |
1984年 | 3篇 |
1983年 | 2篇 |
1982年 | 5篇 |
1981年 | 4篇 |
1980年 | 7篇 |
1979年 | 4篇 |
1978年 | 3篇 |
1977年 | 3篇 |
1976年 | 3篇 |
1975年 | 5篇 |
1974年 | 4篇 |
1973年 | 3篇 |
1970年 | 2篇 |
1937年 | 1篇 |
1931年 | 3篇 |
1929年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有268条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
241.
242.
Technological progress and technical efficiency in Chinese industrial growth: A frontier production function approach 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
We estimate a frontier production function for Chinese industry for the period 1953–1985. Contrary to prior studies based on OLS estimates, we find that Chinese industry has been characterized by a rate of growth of technological progress between 1.8 and 3.6 percent per year. We also find that the capital-saving nature of technological progress has adversely affected Chinese productivity growth because of increases in the capital-labor ratio. The utilization of industrial resources has been quite suboptimal for much of the sample period, with industrial production well off the production frontier. These deviations from efficient resource use reflect well-known political and economic developments that disrupted economic activity. Finally, both technical efficiency and total factor productivity increased appreciably in the period 1978–1985, suggesting that the reforms have had some positive impact on industrial performance. 相似文献
243.
Franz Josef Scholz 《Journal of Consumer Policy》1981,5(1-2):134-139
Ohne Zusammenfassung 相似文献
244.
Josef Schmidhuber Prakash Shetty 《Food Economics - Acta Agriculturae Scandinavica, Section C》2005,2(3):150-166
Considerable increases in food consumption, shifts in consumption patterns and changes in the entire food system have occurred globally. These changes, initially limited to the industrialized world, are now being experienced at an even faster pace in many of the advanced economies of the developing world. The past evolution of this transition in nutrition and lifestyles is by now well documented. Based on FAO's outlook for global food and agriculture, this paper outlines the likely future changes in food consumption patterns and the global trajectory of the nutrition transition over the next 30 years. It presents the main drivers of the nutrition transition and examines their influence on the prospective changes in consumption patterns. The paper illustrates how the current burden of undernourishment and malnutrition in developing countries is likely to compound the adverse effects of the nutrition transition, notably the increasing prevalence of obesity and non-communicable diseases (NCDs); it shows how and where the current problem of undernutrition could create a growing future burden of overweight, obesity and NCDs and that both undernourishment and overnutrition are likely to co-exist for a long time in the vast majority of developing countries, creating a widespread double burden of malnutrition. 相似文献
245.
The Geography of Equity Listing: Why Do Companies List Abroad? 总被引:11,自引:1,他引:11
This paper documents aggregate trends in the foreign listings of companies, and analyzes their distinctive prelisting characteristics and postlisting performance. In 1986–1997, many European companies listed abroad, mainly on U.S. exchanges, while the number of U.S. companies listed in Europe decreased. European companies that cross-list tend to be large and recently privatized firms, and expand their foreign sales after listing abroad. They differ sharply depending on where they cross-list: The U.S. exchanges attract high-tech and export-oriented companies that expand rapidly without significant leveraging. Companies cross-listing within Europe do not grow unusually fast, and increase their leverage after cross-listing. 相似文献
246.
Josef C. Brada 《Economic Systems》2013,37(3):333-344
I review the literature on labor's share of national income in developed and developing countries. These shares have varied systematically over the post-World War II period, rising until the late 1970s and then falling until now. Explanations for the decline in labor's share include technical progress, globalization and a decline in labor's bargaining power, but none of these explanations can account for both the rise and the decline of labor shares over time and for the similar pattern in developed and developing countries. However, movements in oil prices can account for these movements if energy is included in the production function. Such an explanation has broad implications for income distribution, energy conservation and for the modern theory of growth. 相似文献
247.
248.
Josef Solterer 《Forum for Social Economics》2013,42(3):45-49
Eucken, in his paradigm of a functionally competitive social market economy, established the basis for a free market economy which institutionalizes concerns for economic and social justice. The Bishops’ Pastoral (and also the Lay Letter) on the U.S. economy approach the concept of a social and just economy from a Christian moral tradition. A community of interests between these two approaches, as well as Donaldson’s synthesis of Nozick’s and Rawl’s theories of justice, causes a moral-economic dialogue and cross fertilization to emerge. The Bishops postulate that the evolution of a just and fair market economy, as the guarantor of freedom, human dignity, and justice, cannot be left to chance but needs to be consciously guided. Therefore, they emphasize the integration of economic theories and policies with notions of “fairness” and “justice,” advocating a holistic approach in viewing the economic system as an organic whole. This paper shows that the broad economic guidelines, which Bishops suggest, fall within the framework of a functional market economy, i.e., a social market economy. It does not deal with the religious and biblical arguments of the Pastoral Letter. 相似文献
249.
250.
Halling Michael; Pagano Marco; Randl Otto; Zechner Josef 《Review of Financial Studies》2008,21(2):725-761
We analyze the location of stock trading for firms with a UScross-listing. The fraction of trading that occurs in the UnitedStates tends to be larger for companies from countries thatare geographically close to the United States and feature lowfinancial development and poor insider trading protection. Forcompanies based in developed countries, trading volume in theUnited States is larger if the company is small, volatile, andtechnology-oriented, while this does not apply to emerging countryfirms. The domestic turnover rate increases in the cross-listingyear and remains higher for firms based in developed markets,but not for emerging market firms. Domestic trading volume actuallydeclines for companies from countries with poor enforcementof insider trading regulation. 相似文献