首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   84篇
  免费   0篇
财政金融   4篇
工业经济   6篇
计划管理   18篇
经济学   16篇
运输经济   1篇
旅游经济   1篇
贸易经济   14篇
农业经济   4篇
经济概况   20篇
  2024年   1篇
  2021年   1篇
  2020年   2篇
  2019年   3篇
  2018年   4篇
  2017年   2篇
  2016年   1篇
  2015年   3篇
  2014年   5篇
  2013年   10篇
  2012年   4篇
  2011年   4篇
  2010年   3篇
  2009年   7篇
  2008年   4篇
  2007年   2篇
  2006年   5篇
  2005年   2篇
  2004年   2篇
  2003年   1篇
  2001年   1篇
  2000年   1篇
  1996年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   1篇
  1991年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1986年   1篇
  1985年   1篇
  1979年   1篇
  1978年   1篇
  1974年   2篇
  1973年   1篇
  1940年   1篇
  1920年   1篇
  1885年   1篇
排序方式: 共有84条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
41.
Summary This paper provides a survey of the empirical literature on the relative performance of not-for-profit (NFP) organisations for three specific sectors. In particular, we compare the quality and accessibility of services that are provided by hospitals, child care organisations and welfare-to-work (WTW) organisations. Various mechanisms may explain the comparative advantages and disadvantages of not-for-profit organisations, as well as the origins of NFPs. We link these explanations to the actual relative performance of NFPs and discuss the implications for the government in mixed markets, where both for-profit (FP) and NFP organisations are. Our general finding is that NFPs do not make a difference on performance outcomes vis-à-vis FP organisations. It seems that the degree of competition, as well as regulatory policies are more important determinants of market performance.   相似文献   
42.
A detailed evaluation is given of two dutch wage subsidy schemes. Aspects covered are: deadweight, displacement, effects an employment and continuity of labour-force participation. Both aggregate data (time-series and cross-section data) and individual survey data have been used to estimate the various effects.  相似文献   
43.
    
Agriculture and the WTO: time to reconsider the basics? Late 19th century industrial developments generated oversupply in agricultural markets. Free market adjustment proved difficult and many European countries introduced protection. When agricultural prices fell again in the 1930s, all other western countries followed, making international regulation of agricultural trade an urgent matter. Under the New Deal, the USDA moved to a commodity agreements approach via the GATT. Both the US and the EU, however, failed to introduce the required production controls and engaged in increased dumping. When expanded output in the EU led to competitive dumping in grain markets, the US changed its strategy and got an agreement in the Uruguay Round that prescribed reductions in price supports but exempted certain direct payments. Thereupon both blocks substituted direct payments for price supports in ways that allowed them to maintain large exports at prices below their own production costs. In the Doha Round, they are negotiating a further shift in this direction. Developing countries call this disguised dumping. Besides, many least developed countries claim the right to protect their own farmers against cheap imports. They need an agricultural revolution to accommodate population growth and get non‐farm development moving, but low world market prices hamper investment in farming. Redressing this problem and securing long‐term global food security require a balanced system of managed trade rather than the pseudo‐liberalisation that the US and the EU pursue. Agriculture et OMC: et si on revenait aux sources ? A la fin du 19ème siècle, le développement industriel a engendré des surproductions sur les marchés agricoles. Les régulations par le marché se sont révélées difficiles et de nombreux pays européens en sont venus au protectionnisme. Dans les années 30, les prix agricoles se sont à nouveau effondrés, ce qui a conduit à considérer la régulation internationale du commerce comme une affaire importante. Le ‘New Deal’ conduisit I'USDA à s'engager dans un système ?accorcl par produits dans le cadre du GATT. Cependant, ni les Etats‐Unis ni ?Europe ne parvinrent à introduire les contrôles de la production qui auraient été nécessaires. Tous deux s'engagèrent dans des actions de dumping sans cesse plus importantes. Lorsque ?accroissement de la production en Europe conduisit à une concurrence sur les dumpings cérealiers, les Etats‐Unis changérent de stratégic et obtinrent, dans le cadre de ?Uruguay Round, un accord obligeant à réduire les soutiens de prix, tout en autorisant certains paiements directs. De ce fait, les deux blocs remplacèrent les soutiens de prix par des paiements directs, de manière à conserver la possibilityé?exporter de grandes quantités à des prix inférieurs aux coûts de production internes. Dans les négotiations du Doha Round, ils se sont engagés encore plus loin dans cette direction. Les pays en voie de développement appellent cela du dumping déguisé. Beaucoup des moins développés ?entre eux réclament le droit de protéger leurs propres agriculteurs contre les importations à prix de braderie. Ils ont besoin ?une révolution agricole pour faire face à la croissance démographique et déclencher le développement en dehors de ?agriculture, mais les faibles prix internationaux des produits agricoles les empêchent ?investir dans ?agriculture. Pour résoudre ce probléme et garantir à long terme la sécurité alimentaire mondiale, il faudrait trouver un système équilibré de commerce contrôlé, au lieu de la pseudo libéralisation recherchée par les Etats‐Unis et ?Europe. Landwirtschaft und WTO: Ist es an der Zeit, die Grundprinzipien zu überdenken? Die Industrialisierung im späten 19. Jahrhundert hat zu einer Überschussproduktion in der Landwirtschaft geführt. Die Anpassung an die Marktkräfte erwies sich als schwierig, und viele europäische Länder führten eine Agrarprotektion ein. Als die Agrarpreise in den dreiβiger Jahren des vorigen Jahrhunderts wieder fielen, gingen alle westlichen Länder zur Agrarprotektion über und machten damit eine internationale Regelungen des Agrarhandels zu einer dringenden Angelegenheit. Das US Landwirtschaftsministerium führte unter der neuen Regelung des GATT Warenabkommen ein. Sowohl die USA als auch die EU versäumten es jedoch, Angebotsbeschränkungen einzuführen; stattdessen subventionierten sie die Ausfuhren. Als die gestiegenen Exporte der EU zu einem Subventionswettbewerb im Getreidehandel führten, anderten die USA ihre Strategic‐ Sie erreichten in der Uruguay‐Runde, dass Preisstützungsmaβnahmen reduziert werden mussten, dass aber einige Formen von Direktzahlungen weiterhin erlaubt wurden. Als Folge der Vereinbarung haben beide Parteien Preisstützung durch Direktzahlungen ersetzt und es dadurch ermöglicht, dass groβe Mengen zu Preisen exportiert werden konnten, die unter den Produktionskosten liegen. In der Doha‐Runde verhandeln die Parteien in der gleichen Richtung. Entwicklungsländer nennen dieses verstecktes Dumping. Auβerdem verlangen viele am wenigsten entwickelte Länder, ihre Landwirtschaft gegen Billigimporte auch stützen zu dürfen. Diese Länder benötigen eine landwirtschaftliche Revolution, um das Bevölkerungswachstum zu verkraften und die nicht landwirtschaftliche Entwicklung zu fördern. Niedrige Weltmarktpreise dämpfen landwirtschaftliche Investitionen. Eine Berücksichtigung dieses Problems und die Sicherung der globalen Nahrungsmittelversorgung erfordern ein ausgewogenes System von administriertem Handel und nicht den Pseudo‐Liberalismus den die USA und die EU verfolgen.  相似文献   
44.
This paper aims to come to a better understanding of the meaning of ‘ethnic’ in ethnic entrepreneurship for second- and third-generation ethnic Chinese entrepreneurs in Bangkok, Thailand. Research on ethnic Chinese entrepreneurship in Southeast Asia typically investigates the dominance, attributed to specific ‘Chinese’ cultural values and strong intra-ethnic networks, of the ethnic Chinese in business and entrepreneurship. Our research among second- and third-generations shows an inclination of the interviewees to emphasize the irrelevance of their ‘ethnic’ Chinese background in entrepreneurship. To understand the meanings of the expressed irrelevance, we argue that it is constructive to incorporate a historical/generational approach of the ethnic group (migration history, nationalism) and of the business (social organization) into the study of ethnic entrepreneurship. The contribution to ethnic entrepreneurship research is threefold. Firstly, we show how a generational lens provides a more nuanced understanding of the ‘ethnic’ in ethnic entrepreneurship. Secondly, we show how incorporating the historical context helps to position business conduct in the social/societal experiences of entrepreneurs. Finally, our case study of ethnic Chinese entrepreneurs in Thailand brings an Asian perspective to ethnic entrepreneurship debates that generally concern European and North American research studies and thus hopes to inspire future comparative research.  相似文献   
45.
46.
The purpose of the interview was to talk to David Lowenthal about the imminent release of his updated version of The Past Is a Foreign Country, a seminal work on history, memory and nostalgia which profoundly influenced debates on heritage culture following its initial publication in 1985. David served in the US Army during World War Two and during his long and distinguished career as a cultural geographer taught at Vassar College and the University of the West Indies. He is now emeritus professor of geography at University College London. His books include West Indian Societies (1972), Landscape Meanings and Values (with Edmund Penning-Rowsell, 1986), The Politics of the Past (with Peter Gathercole, 1989) and The Heritage Crusade and the Spoils of History (1997). The interview took place in London on 24 September 2012.  相似文献   
47.
    
Abstract

This article examines the political footprint of a new wave of grassroots humanitarian organisations in the informal refugee camp, popularly dubbed ‘The Jungle’, in Calais, northern France. Set against the formal humanitarian void created by the French state barring of international aid agencies, and the abject conditions of camp life, we trace the shifting socio-spatial remit and progressive politicisation of these ‘apolitical’ organisations as they encounter a crisis of human rights in the Jungle, prior to its violent demolition by state decree in October 2016. In foregrounding the organisational perspectives of Play4Calais and the Refugee Youth Service, and their unorthodox deployment of play, sport, cinema and art, we reveal a grassroots humanitarian praxis which offers an alternative to the large-scale ‘professionalised’ registers of aid delivery. By virtue of their relative informality, spatial proximity and volunteer activism, these grassroots organisations not only stand in tension with the violent border sovereignties of neoliberal states, but open up the inchoate possibility for political struggle and refugee-centred claims-making over the right to inhabit the ‘exceptional’ space of the camp.  相似文献   
48.
We examine the impact of competition on outcome and process indicators of hospital quality. While earlier literature on the relationship between competition and hospital quality mainly focused on outcome indicators, we argue that the inclusion of process indicators in the analysis can provide supplementary information about the effect of competitive pressure on hospitals’ incentives. In particular, these indicators are less noisy than outcome indicators and are important as a management tool. Our panel dataset covers all Dutch general and academic hospitals in the period 2004–2008, during which the transparency of hospital quality information increased substantially due to the disclosure of hospitals’ quality indicators. We find that competition among hospitals located within the hospital catchment area explains differences in several process indicators, but fails to explain differences in outcome indicators. The results suggest that hospitals facing more competition organize diagnostic processes more efficiently; however, they have more operation cancellations at short notice and more delays of hip fracture injury operations for elderly patients. This suggests that competition affects the allocation of hospital personnel efforts even when outcomes have not been affected.  相似文献   
49.
Experience Rating and the Inflow into Disability Insurance   总被引:2,自引:0,他引:2  
Pierre Koning 《De Economist》2009,157(3):315-335
This paper examines the effects of experience rating on the inflow into disability insurance (DI) in the Netherlands, using unique longitudinal administrative data from the social benefit administration. We follow a difference-in-differences approach to identify the impact of changes in DI premiums. Due to unawareness of the experience rating system, employers seem to have been triggered to increase preventative activities, once they have experienced increases in DI premium rates. We find this impact to be substantial, amounting to a 15% reduction of the DI inflow.  相似文献   
50.
    
We assess the impact of the phasing‐out of quotas on European clothing imports within the framework of the phase‐out of the Multi‐Fiber Agreement and the accession of the CEEC. We use 1996 data on trade barriers for 20 categories of clothing products and 22 exporters. The estimation of a standard gravity equation concludes that tariffs have a large and negative impact as expected but seldom corroborated in the literature. The negative impact of non‐tariff barriers also appears clearly after controlling for an endogeneity bias by the instrumental variables method. The phasing‐out of quotas should increase EU imports by 20%.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号