全文获取类型
收费全文 | 17435篇 |
免费 | 8篇 |
国内免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2752篇 |
工业经济 | 790篇 |
计划管理 | 2702篇 |
经济学 | 3997篇 |
综合类 | 541篇 |
运输经济 | 13篇 |
旅游经济 | 9篇 |
贸易经济 | 4536篇 |
农业经济 | 51篇 |
经济概况 | 1435篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 574篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 9篇 |
2022年 | 24篇 |
2021年 | 28篇 |
2020年 | 15篇 |
2019年 | 18篇 |
2018年 | 2310篇 |
2017年 | 2071篇 |
2016年 | 1219篇 |
2015年 | 110篇 |
2014年 | 114篇 |
2013年 | 104篇 |
2012年 | 506篇 |
2011年 | 2011篇 |
2010年 | 1887篇 |
2009年 | 1569篇 |
2008年 | 1560篇 |
2007年 | 1903篇 |
2006年 | 102篇 |
2005年 | 425篇 |
2004年 | 474篇 |
2003年 | 555篇 |
2002年 | 258篇 |
2001年 | 69篇 |
2000年 | 53篇 |
1999年 | 1篇 |
1998年 | 17篇 |
1997年 | 1篇 |
1996年 | 15篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 13篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
121.
We examine the impact of financial reforms on efficient reallocation of capital within and between sectors in South Africa using firm-level panel data for the period 1991–2008. The measure of efficient allocation of capital is based on the Tobin’s Q. We find that financial reforms are associated with improvements in within-sector, but not between-sector allocation of capital. These results imply that for South Africa to unleash the potential for take-off that is often associated with reallocation of resources from the primitive to modern sectors, reforms that focus beyond the financial sector are necessary. While more research is necessary to determine what would fully constitute such additional reforms, our analysis shows that reforms that improve the quality of economic institutions may be a step in the right the direction. 相似文献
122.
Karl-Göran Mäler 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2007,37(1):63-75
Green net national product was thought to be one way of measuring sustainable income. However, David Pearce understood that
a better measure of sustainable development was to look at what a generation is leaving in form of capital assets to later
generations. In this article, his arguments and insights are highlighted against recent theoretical advances. 相似文献
123.
Tetsuo Ono 《Economic Theory》2007,33(3):549-577
Pension benefits in old age establish a disincentive to save in youth, thereby yielding lower levels of capital stock and
the wage rate. As a result, the trade union has an incentive to change the composition of its two targets: employment and
the wage rate. This paper develops a model that includes employment effects of public pensions via capital accumulation and
union wage setting. Within this framework, we consider how contribution rates to the pension system influence the level and
time path of the unemployment rate. It is demonstrated that (1) a higher contribution rate results in a lower unemployment
rate, and (2) the economy with a high (low) contribution rate experiences monotone convergence towards (oscillatory convergence
towards or a period-2 cycle around) the steady state.
The author would like to thank an anonymous referee, Kazutoshi Miyazawa, and seminar participants at Osaka University for
their useful comments and suggestions, and Masako Ikefuji and Hiroaki Yamagami for their research assistance. Financial support
from the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science (JSPS) through a Grant-in-Aid for Young Scientists (B) (No.17730131),
the Asahi Glass Foundation, the Japan Economic Research Foundation and the 21st Century COE Program (Osaka University) is
gratefully acknowledged. All remaining errors are mine. 相似文献
124.
We estimate a semiparametric dynamic panel data model by the local linear kernel method and we interpret the slope of the
nonparametric component function as a varying slope coefficient. Thus, the slope coefficient is a smooth, but otherwise unknown,
function of some of the regressors. A Monte Carlo experiment is reported to examine the finite sample performance of the local
linear estimator. We apply the estimation method to a labor supply equation for men from the triannual Survey of Income and
Program Participation (SIPP). Specification tests based on the estimated labor supply elasticities, partial adjustment coefficients,
and residuals demonstrate the improvements from a semiparametric partially linear model. Our empirical results point to a
need by economists to revisit the issue of the speed of labor market adjustment to policy induced shifts in labor demand and
to take more formal econometric account of heterogeneity in wage effects when studying the distributional consequences of
tax reforms for labor supply earnings.
First version received: July 2000/Final version received: January 2001 相似文献
125.
Durand (J Finance 12:348–363, 1957) shows that the classical St. Petersburg paradox can apply to the valuation of a firm whose dividends grow at a constant rate forever. To capture a more realistic pattern of dividends, we model the dividend growth rate as a mean reverting process, and then use the capital asset pricing model to derive the risk-adjusted present value. The model generates an equivalent St. Petersburg game. The long-run growth rate of the payoffs (dividends) is dominant in driving the value of the game (firm), and the condition under which the value is finite is less restrictive than that of the standard game. 相似文献
126.
Spatial welfare economics versus ecological footprint: modeling agglomeration,externalities and trade 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Fabio Grazi Jeroen C. J. M. van den Bergh Piet Rietveld 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2007,38(1):135-153
A welfare framework for the analysis of the spatial dimensions of sustainability is developed. It covers agglomeration effects,
interregional trade, negative environmental externalities, and various land use categories. The model is used to compare rankings
of spatial configurations according to evaluations based on social welfare and ecological footprint indicators. Five spatial
configurations are considered for this purpose. The exercise is operationalized with the help of a two-region model of the
economy, that is, in line with the ‘new economic geography.’ By generating a number of numerical ‘counter-examples,’ it is
shown that the footprint method is inconsistent with an approach aimed at maximum social welfare. Unless environmental externalities
are such a large problem that they overwhelm all other components of economic well-being, a ‘spatial welfare economic’ approach
delivers totally different rankings of alternative land use configurations than the ecological footprint.
相似文献
127.
Sue H. Mialon 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》2007,31(1):109-123
We compare various access pricing rules in the two-way access model. We show that the Generalized Efficient Component Pricing
Rule (TECPR) leads to a lower equilibrium price than does the Efficient Component Pricing Rule, (ECPR) marginal cost pricing,
(MCP) and any non-negative fixed access charges.
相似文献
128.
In general rational expectations equilibrium (REE), as introduced in Radner (Econometrica 47:655–678, 1978) in an Arrow–Debreu–McKenzie
setting with uncertainty, does not exist. Moreover, it fails to be fully Pareto optimal and incentive compatible and is also
not implementable as a perfect Bayesian equilibrium of an extensive form game (Glycopantis et al. in Econ Theory 26:765–791,
2005). The lack of all the above properties is mainly due to the fact that the agents are supposed to predict the equilibrium
market clearing price (as agent’s expected maximized utility is conditioned on the information that equilibrium prices reveal),
which leads inevitably to the presumption that agents know all the primitives in the economy, i.e., random initial endowments,
random utility functions and private information sets. To get around this problematic equilibrium notion, we introduce a new
concept called Bayesian–Walrasian equilibrium (BWE) which has Bayesian features. In particular, agents try to predict the market-clearing prices using Bayesian updating
and evaluate their consumption in terms of Bayesian price estimates, which are different for each individual. In this framework
agents maximize expected utility conditioned on their own private information about the state of nature, subject to a Bayesian
estimated budget constraint. Market clearing is not an intrinsic part of the definition of BWE. However, both in the case
of perfect foresight and in the case of symmetric information BWE leads to a statewise market clearing; it then becomes an
ex post Walrasian equilibrium allocation. This new BWE exists under standard assumptions, in contrast to the REE. In particular,
we show that our new BWE exists in the well-known example in Kreps (J Econ Theory 14:32–43, 1977), where REE fails to exist.
This work was done in the Spring of 2005, when EJB was a visiting professor at the University of Illinois. 相似文献
129.
We examine risk profiles of the Portuguese stock market index component stocks using a novel approach to the classical capital asset pricing model (CAPM). Specifically, we estimate the CAPM via fractal regressions that allow studying the marginal effects at selected scales. In this way, we can reveal whether the risk is perceived differently by market participants with different investment horizons. Apart from the analysis itself, we provide new statistical insights into the issue of separating and comparing the scale-specific effects with statistical validity. We find several stocks deviating from an expected risk perception homogeneity across investment horizons. This is true for both analysed periods, i.e. before and after the global financial crisis. There are also several stocks that changed their relationship to the market portfolio in between, which has strong implications for possible portfolio construction. The proposed methodology is not limited to financial topics but can be used in any discipline where the scale-specific marginal effects might be of interest. 相似文献
130.
Economic reforms,efficiency and productivity in Chinese banking 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
This paper analyzes the impact of banking reforms on efficiency and total factor productivity (TFP) change in Chinese banking
industry. Using an input distance function, we find that joint-equity banks are more efficient than wholly state-owned banks
(WSOBs). Furthermore, both WSOBs and joint-equity banks are found to be operating slightly below their optimal size, suggesting
potential advantages in expansion of their businesses. Overall, TFP growth was 4.4% per annum for the sample period 1993–2002.
Joint-equity banks experienced much higher growth in TFP (5.5% per annum) compared to the WSOBs (1.4% per annum).
相似文献