全文获取类型
收费全文 | 8263篇 |
免费 | 254篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 1728篇 |
工业经济 | 710篇 |
计划管理 | 1326篇 |
经济学 | 1744篇 |
综合类 | 110篇 |
运输经济 | 94篇 |
旅游经济 | 162篇 |
贸易经济 | 1744篇 |
农业经济 | 243篇 |
经济概况 | 584篇 |
信息产业经济 | 4篇 |
邮电经济 | 68篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 57篇 |
2022年 | 47篇 |
2021年 | 80篇 |
2020年 | 120篇 |
2019年 | 195篇 |
2018年 | 218篇 |
2017年 | 245篇 |
2016年 | 212篇 |
2015年 | 174篇 |
2014年 | 275篇 |
2013年 | 949篇 |
2012年 | 311篇 |
2011年 | 355篇 |
2010年 | 323篇 |
2009年 | 364篇 |
2008年 | 324篇 |
2007年 | 277篇 |
2006年 | 253篇 |
2005年 | 284篇 |
2004年 | 235篇 |
2003年 | 241篇 |
2002年 | 233篇 |
2001年 | 193篇 |
2000年 | 173篇 |
1999年 | 175篇 |
1998年 | 142篇 |
1997年 | 152篇 |
1996年 | 125篇 |
1995年 | 118篇 |
1994年 | 124篇 |
1993年 | 113篇 |
1992年 | 107篇 |
1991年 | 95篇 |
1990年 | 65篇 |
1989年 | 74篇 |
1988年 | 68篇 |
1987年 | 66篇 |
1986年 | 67篇 |
1985年 | 112篇 |
1984年 | 89篇 |
1983年 | 81篇 |
1982年 | 89篇 |
1981年 | 64篇 |
1980年 | 73篇 |
1979年 | 66篇 |
1978年 | 57篇 |
1977年 | 60篇 |
1976年 | 55篇 |
1974年 | 31篇 |
1973年 | 20篇 |
排序方式: 共有8517条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
101.
This study documents that the survival of start-ups is central in explaining the relationship between entry and regional employment growth. Distinguishing between start-ups according to the period of their survival shows that the positive effect of new business formation on employment growth is mainly driven by those new businesses that are strong enough to remain in the market for a certain period of time. This result is especially pronounced for the relationship between the surviving start-ups and employment growth in incumbent businesses indicating that there are significantly positive indirect effects of new business formation on regional development. We draw conclusions for policy and make suggestions for further research. 相似文献
102.
This article uses Australian panel data for the years 2001–2009 to estimate returns to general experience, job and occupational tenure. We pay particular attention to issues of unobserved heterogeneity bias in our estimations. We find that both general experience and occupational tenure have statistically and numerically significant effects on wage outcomes, even after controlling for unobserved heterogeneity. Job tenure on the other hand only seems to matter in OLS regressions that do not control for heterogeneity biases. Once these biases are controlled for, only a modest effect from job tenure remains. The inclusion of occupational tenure in the estimating equation tends to negate even this modest job tenure effect. The only exception to this is for workers in large organizations. For these workers a small but statistically significant effect from job tenure remains, even once we have controlled for heterogeneity and included occupational tenure in the estimating equation. The results reported in this article have implications for the various theories of the labour market that predict upward-sloping wage-job-tenure profiles. 相似文献
103.
Wolfram Berger Michael Pickhardt Athanassios Pitsoulis Aloys Prinz Jordi Sardà 《Applied economics》2013,45(18):2190-2204
This article presents new estimates of the Greek underground economy and explores the link between the underground economy and aggregate debt. We show that the Greek underground economy has been underestimated heavily and has been on a rising trend again since Greece adopted the Euro. We also present evidence that the size of the underground economy is positively related to the debt-to-GDP ratio, implying that fighting the underground economy is also conducive to financial and macroeconomic stability. Our results suggest that for our sample of 11 EMU member countries, the loss of the inflation tax as an economic policy instrument had drastic consequences. While the underground economy did not have a statistically significant impact on aggregate debt before the introduction of the Euro, it has pushed up the debt-to-GDP ratio in our sample since. 相似文献
104.
This paper studies the use of patent statistics in identifying four aspects of technological structure, namely, the potential knowledge pool, cumulativeness, inter-firm homogeneity in technology levels, and the scope of innovations. The firms are sampled from the chemical (CHEM), the computer (COM) and the electrical and electronic (EE) industries worldwide. Using the proxies defined, we find that (i) the contributions of intra-industry spillover are low, at 12%, 10%, and 9% for the three industries respectively; (ii) they can internalize 15%, 19% and 13% of their previous research efforts respectively; and (iii) a positive relationship between knowledge spillover and technology overlap, and between scope of innovation and number of patents being cited in future. 相似文献
105.
Michael Assous 《European Journal of the History of Economic Thought》2013,20(2):305-322
AbstractIn 1933, Irving Fisher proposed an explanation for the Great Depression based on the distinction between the price level and price change effect of deflation in a context of over-indebtedness. This paper compares the debt-deflation theory of Fisher (1933) with the dynamic depression process he had expounded almost 20 years earlier in the Purchasing Power of Money (1911). The role played by both price level and price change effects in the analyses of Fisher (1933, 1911) are clarified in the context of the disequilibrium model of Tobin (1975). More precisely, we show that the stationary equilibrium is assumed to be locally unstable according to Fisher's 1911 insights and globally unstable according to his 1933 analysis. 相似文献
106.
Professor Benarroch Michael 《International economic journal》2013,27(2):65-83
This paper examines the dynamics of learning and experience that underlie technology transfer using a North-South trade model with a continuum of goods. Since North is historically more experienced than South, it initially produces the most advanced goods and pays higher wages. Whenever there is a market-driven transfer of technology and production over time, there will be some wage convergence as South gradually gains experience. Nevertheless, wage inequality must persist in the steady state. Product innovation typically increases steady-state wage inequality because new goods are produced in North, and North ultimately learns than South. [F12, O19] 相似文献
107.
Margo Bergman G. Dirk Mateer Michael Reksulak Jonathan C. Rork Rick K. Wilson David Zirkle 《The Journal of economic education》2013,44(4):405-421
The authors detail an urban economics experiment that is easily run in the classroom. The experiment has a flexible design that allows the instructor to explore how congestion, zoning, public transportation, and taxation levels determine the bid–rent function. Heterogeneous agents in the experiment compete for land use using a simple auction mechanism. Using the data that is collected, a bid–rent function is derived, and the experimental treatment is altered over the course of three sessions to uncover core concepts in urban economics. Moreover, this provides a tangible experience that can be used to help undergraduates relate to urban issues such as the steep rent gradient found around many larger colleges and universities. 相似文献
108.
Michael A. MacDowell 《The Journal of economic education》2013,44(3):210-212
L. Scott Miller confronts us with the inadequacy of the schooling establishment's response to the educational needs of the special and rapidly growing group of minority students. Restructuring is urged as the most effective approach for meeting the urgent needs of disadvantaged at-risk students. Two experienced and prominent economics educators comment on the challenge and policy proposals. 相似文献
109.
110.
Between 1978 and 1994, the University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill experienced a cycle in the number of economics degrees it conferred that was more pronounced than that experienced nationally. A random sample of UNC economics majors between 1983 and 1994 showed that students screened out of the business curriculum made an economics major their second choice. 相似文献