全文获取类型
收费全文 | 16856篇 |
免费 | 4篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2665篇 |
工业经济 | 766篇 |
计划管理 | 2566篇 |
经济学 | 3899篇 |
综合类 | 482篇 |
运输经济 | 2篇 |
旅游经济 | 1篇 |
贸易经济 | 4504篇 |
农业经济 | 3篇 |
经济概况 | 1355篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 573篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 3篇 |
2022年 | 1篇 |
2021年 | 1篇 |
2020年 | 3篇 |
2019年 | 12篇 |
2018年 | 2302篇 |
2017年 | 2061篇 |
2016年 | 1209篇 |
2015年 | 95篇 |
2014年 | 92篇 |
2013年 | 70篇 |
2012年 | 444篇 |
2011年 | 1948篇 |
2010年 | 1835篇 |
2009年 | 1521篇 |
2008年 | 1512篇 |
2007年 | 1871篇 |
2006年 | 66篇 |
2005年 | 389篇 |
2004年 | 464篇 |
2003年 | 552篇 |
2002年 | 251篇 |
2001年 | 62篇 |
2000年 | 49篇 |
1999年 | 1篇 |
1998年 | 16篇 |
1996年 | 14篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 13篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
991.
We examine three tools that can enhance coordination success in a repeated multiple-choice coordination game. Gradualism means that the game starts as an easy coordination problem and moves gradually to a more difficult one. The Endogenous Ascending mechanism implies that a gradual increase in the upper bound of coordination occurs only if coordination with the Pareto superior equilibrium in a stage game is attained. The Endogenous Descending mechanism requires that when the game’s participants fail to coordinate, the level of the next coordination game be adjusted such that the game becomes simpler. We show that gradualism may not always work, but in such instances, its effect can be reinforced by endogeneity. Our laboratory experiment provides evidence that a mechanism that combines three tools, herein termed the “Gradualism with Endogenous Ascending and Descending (GEAD)” mechanism, works well. We discuss how the GEAD mechanism can be applied to real-life situations that suffer from coordination failure. 相似文献
992.
We explore the effect of fixed versus dynamic group membership on public good provision. In a novel experimental design, we modify the traditional voluntary contribution mechanism (VCM) by periodically replacing old members of a group with new members over time. Under this dynamic, overlapping generations matching protocol we find that average contributions experience significantly less decay over time relative to a traditional VCM environment with fixed group membership and a common termination date. These findings suggest that the traditional pattern of contribution and decay seen in many public goods experiments may not accurately reflect behavior in groups with changing membership, as is the case in many real-world environments. 相似文献
993.
Cornelius A. Rietveld Petri Böckerman Jutta Viinikainen Alex Bryson Olli Raitakari Jaakko Pehkonen 《Journal of Bioeconomics》2016,18(1):53-64
Creatine is a nitrogenous organic acid which supplies energy to body cells and enhances physical performance. Using the Young Finns Study combined with the Finnish Linked employer-employee data we show that quantities of creatine measured in 1980 prior to labour market entry affect entrepreneurial success as measured by capital income accumulation over the period 1993–2010 (in particular for females). However, we do not find evidence that creatine affects the propensity to become an entrepreneur. Our study contributes to the emerging literature on biomarkers and entrepreneurship. 相似文献
994.
Nicolaus Tideman 《Journal of Bioeconomics》2016,18(2):99-102
Gordon Tullock was rational to a fault, and he tried to insist that others be fully rational, confronting all with any inconsistency in their thinking. He loved to be shocking. He was also quite generous. Tullock’s willingness to take a chance, as editor of Public Choice, on a paper that he did not understand led to the publication of the most widely cited paper ever published in the journal. 相似文献
995.
Jason Oakes 《Journal of Bioeconomics》2016,18(2):137-151
I am interested in how models, practices, and concepts travel across specialties and thereby change and are changed in turn. In the present essay I discuss Gordon Tullock’s ideas about the relationship between biology and economics in the light of his correspondence with the biologist Garrett Hardin. Tullock contributed to one of Hardin’s edited projects, but they took different approaches to related problems, which I characterize as problems of coordinated action. Tullock saw that he and Hardin were up to a similar line of inquiry, and Hardin engaged with him up to a point, but ultimately the biologist differed with the economist regarding the potential for the reliability of a regulating power such as the state. 相似文献
996.
Does Protestantism favour entrepreneurship more than Catholicism does? We provide a novel way to answer this question by comparing Protestant and Catholic minorities using Swiss census data. Exploiting the strong adhesion of religious minorities to their denomination’ ethical principles and the historical determination of the geographical distribution of denominations across Swiss cantons, we find that Protestantism is associated with a significantly higher propensity for entrepreneurship. The estimated difference ranges between 1.5 and 3.2 % points, it is larger the smaller the size of the religious minority, it is mainly driven by prime age male entrepreneurs and it stands up to a number of robustness checks. No effects are found when comparing religious majorities, suggesting that the implications of religious ethical norms on economic outcomes emerge only when such norms are fully internalized. 相似文献
997.
998.
Andrew David Allan Smith 《The Review of Austrian Economics》2016,29(2):139-161
This paper will focus on the ambitious plan for regulation embodied in the Dominion Fisheries Act of 1868, a law passed by the Canadian federal parliament in its very first year of existence. The 1868 law was intended to bring the nation's fisheries firmly under the control of officials employed by the new federal government. The paper argues that 1868 law, which was designed to address what would today be called Tragedy of the Commons problems, was a product of the hubris identified by Hayek as "the fatal conceit." The centralized and bureaucratic approach to governing fisheries represented by the 1868 Fisheries Act did not work well because the knowledge that would have been required for successful management of fisheries was highly dispersed. Drawing on Hayek and the Bloomington School, this paper argues that the experience of Canada's fisheries sector in the generation after 1868 illustrates the problems with centralized management Common-Pool Resources. In the 1890s, the centralized approach represented by the Fisheries Act of 1868 was replaced by a more flexible and decentralized system Hayek's theory of knowledge would suggest the reversal of centralization over environmental policy in the 1890s was a positive development that helped Canadians to reconcile the goals of economic development and the protection of the environment. The Hayekian paradigm suggests that control over environmental policy should be devolved downwards to the levels of government closest to resource users. 相似文献
999.
1000.