首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   206篇
  免费   1篇
财政金融   19篇
工业经济   7篇
计划管理   28篇
经济学   25篇
综合类   5篇
旅游经济   1篇
贸易经济   88篇
农业经济   13篇
经济概况   20篇
邮电经济   1篇
  2021年   1篇
  2018年   3篇
  2017年   4篇
  2016年   3篇
  2015年   5篇
  2014年   8篇
  2013年   9篇
  2012年   6篇
  2011年   4篇
  2010年   6篇
  2009年   8篇
  2008年   8篇
  2007年   10篇
  2006年   9篇
  2005年   8篇
  2004年   5篇
  2003年   4篇
  2002年   7篇
  2001年   3篇
  2000年   3篇
  1999年   2篇
  1998年   7篇
  1997年   3篇
  1996年   2篇
  1995年   5篇
  1994年   4篇
  1993年   3篇
  1992年   7篇
  1991年   2篇
  1990年   2篇
  1989年   3篇
  1988年   5篇
  1987年   2篇
  1986年   3篇
  1985年   6篇
  1984年   3篇
  1983年   5篇
  1982年   1篇
  1981年   3篇
  1980年   3篇
  1979年   2篇
  1978年   4篇
  1977年   3篇
  1976年   4篇
  1975年   1篇
  1974年   3篇
  1973年   3篇
  1967年   1篇
  1962年   1篇
排序方式: 共有207条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
161.
For some years now, the ECB is responding to the current deflationary phase and slow economic growth in the Euro zone with a low interest policy and bond purchasing programs. This has led to a surge in real asset prices, such as real estate. Inflation in residential property prices however varies regionally as a result of differences in supply elasticities. Thus, highest growth in prices could be observed in metropolitan areas. This article shows that such developments may lead to an increasing housing wealth inequality due to existing housing wealth distributions, local differences in homeownership, and barriers to entry to the property market. Additionally, these effects might be strengthened by indirect effects, such as filtering, rent-seeking, gentrification, and segregation.  相似文献   
162.
Germany has realized tremendous growth rates in the aftermath of the Second World War. Since the early 1970s, growth rates declined and settled down at a more or less constant rate of 2% per year, only to experience a renewed negative trend around the early 2000s. Estimating GMM growth models in a panel of 187 countries between 1970 and 2010, we illustrate that large parts of historical welfare increases have emerged due to conditional convergence, human capital accumulation, and innovation activity. Whereas conditional convergence was the main driver behind the extraordinary postwar growth rates in Germany, human capital accumulation in Germany currently lags behind the average level of most developed countries. While this may explain the moderate position of Germany in the group of the 25 richest countries, the developed countries on their part are experiencing a period of below-average GDP growth. In nearly all advanced economies, growth reveals a downward trend since the turn of the millennium. We argue that this decline must be traced back to a general lack of radically new ideas in the world economy. The explanation of the German growth crisis may thus be considered a blueprint of the situation in developed economies.  相似文献   
163.
164.

Forum

The European single market — How far from completion?  相似文献   
165.
A monopolist offerings variants on a Salop circle is analyzed with respect to his choice of product variants and prices. Although we assume a uniform distribution of tastes, the profit-maximizing pattern is not equidistant in variants and prices are not the same for all variants.Instead, under fairly general circumstances, there exists at least one cheap variant (special offer) around which the more expensive ones are clustered. This result depends on the assumption that the market size is not fixed as in most other models of this sort, but depends on prices in a straightforward manner.  相似文献   
166.
Felix Bernstein     
Felix Bernstein was a mathematician and statistician who is remembered for the "Schröder-Bernstein Theorem" of set theory. He was appointed director in 1907 of what he was to develop into the Göttingen Institute for Mathematical Statistics, and in 1911 was involved in the formulation and proof of what became known as the Borel-Cantelli lemmas. Bernstein worked out in 1924 the correct hypothesis for the genetic transmission of human bloodgroups, on the basis of the available statistical material.  相似文献   
167.
168.
Food risks may be caused by malpractice of suppliers who exploit the fact that their production processes and resulting product properties cannot be directly observed by buyers. The probability of malpractice increases with the profits that can be earned through opportunistic behavior. In this paper, we develop a moral hazard model for the empirical analyses of behavioral risks. It accounts for the essential fact that incomplete inspection and tracing increase the profitability of rule-breaking behavior, and that monitoring, tracing and sanctioning are costly. Using the model, we first demonstrate how to design efficient contracts in various situations. In a case study, we then analyze farmers’ incentives with regard to the minimum waiting period after fungicide use. Data are gathered in interviews with three large-scale German farmers and a grain dealer. We find that, while their perception of parameters varies widely, high temptations for rule-breaking arise in some cases. We conclude that empirical moral hazard analyses have significant potential to shed light on behavioral risks.  相似文献   
169.
The literature on unemployment has mostly focused on labor market issues while the impact of capital formation is largely neglected. Job creation is often thought to be a matter of encouraging more employment on a given capital stock. In contrast, this paper explicitly deals with the long–run consequences of institutional shocks on capital formation and employment. It is shown that the usual tradeoff between employment and wages disappears in the long run. In line with an appropriation model, the estimated values for the long–run elasticities of substitution between capital and labor for Germany and France are substantially greater than one.  相似文献   
170.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号