全文获取类型
收费全文 | 106篇 |
免费 | 2篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 23篇 |
工业经济 | 7篇 |
计划管理 | 16篇 |
经济学 | 40篇 |
综合类 | 2篇 |
贸易经济 | 17篇 |
经济概况 | 3篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 1篇 |
2020年 | 7篇 |
2019年 | 4篇 |
2018年 | 2篇 |
2017年 | 3篇 |
2016年 | 2篇 |
2015年 | 3篇 |
2014年 | 3篇 |
2013年 | 1篇 |
2012年 | 10篇 |
2011年 | 7篇 |
2010年 | 4篇 |
2009年 | 2篇 |
2008年 | 7篇 |
2007年 | 5篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 4篇 |
2004年 | 5篇 |
2002年 | 1篇 |
2000年 | 2篇 |
1999年 | 1篇 |
1998年 | 3篇 |
1997年 | 2篇 |
1996年 | 1篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1991年 | 1篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1988年 | 1篇 |
1987年 | 2篇 |
1984年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 1篇 |
1982年 | 5篇 |
1981年 | 1篇 |
1980年 | 2篇 |
1979年 | 1篇 |
1978年 | 1篇 |
1976年 | 1篇 |
1975年 | 1篇 |
1973年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有108条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
21.
In many industries firms have to make quantity decisions before knowing the exact state of demand. In such cases, channel
members have to decide which firm will own the units until demand uncertainty is resolved. The decision about who should retain
ownership depends on the balance of benefit and risk to each member. Ownership, after all, is costly. Whichever member owns
the units accepts the risk of loss if more units are produced than can be sold. But ownership also grants firms the flexibility
to respond to demand once it becomes known by adjusting price. In this study, we analyze ownership decisions in distribution
channels and how those decisions are affected by demand uncertainty. We model demand based on micro-modeling of consumer utility
functions and capture demand uncertainty related to market size and price sensitivity. This study shows that as long as the
degree of uncertainty about market size is intermediate, the retailer and the manufacturer both benefit when the manufacturer
maintains ownership of the units. But when there is substantial uncertainty about market size, the retailer and the channel
are better off if the retailer takes ownership but the manufacturer still prefers to maintain ownership. Thus, there is potential
for channel conflict regarding ownership under high levels of uncertainty. We show that, using product returns, the manufacturer
can achieve the same outcome under retailer ownership as under manufacturer ownership. This provides an additional new rationale
for the prevalence of product returns. The first-best outcome (from the perspective of total channel profit), however, is
under retailer ownership without product returns when uncertainty is high (i.e., product returns reduce the total channel
profit). Negotiations between the manufacturer and the retailer can lead to the first-best outcome but only under quite restrictive
constraints that include direct side payments by the retailer to the manufacturer and the retailer being pessimistic about
its outside option (when an agreement cannot be reached) during the negotiation. 相似文献
22.
Gadi Fibich Arieh Gavious Oded Lowengart 《Journal of the Academy of Marketing Science》2005,33(1):66-78
The authors derive an expression for the price elasticity of demand in the presence of reference price effects that includes
a component resulting from the presence of gains and losses in consumer evaluations. The effect of reference price is most
noticeable immediately after a price change, before consumers have had time to adjust their reference price. As a result,
immediate-term price elasticity is higher than long-term elasticity, which describes the response of demand long after a price
change, when reference price effects are negligible. Furthermore, because of the differential effect of gains and losses,
immediate-term price elasticity for price increases and price decreases is not equal. The authors provide a quantitative definition
for the terms immediate term and long term, using the average interpurchase time and the discrete “memory” parameter. Practical
consequences of the distinction between immediate- and long-term elasticities for the estimation and use of elasticity values
are discussed.
Gadi Fibich (fibich@math.tau.ac.il) is an associate professor in the Department of Applied Mathematics at Tel Aviv University. This research
grew out of his interest in applications of mathematical modeling to economics and management science. He is currently working
on auction theory.
Arieh Gavious (ariehg@bgumail.bgu.ac.il) is a senior lecturer in the Department of Industrial Engineering at Ben Gurion University, Israel.
His interest is in application of game theory to economics and management science problems. His current interest is in auction
theory.
Oded Lowengart (odedl@bgumail.bgu.ac.il) is a senior lecturer in the Department of Business Administration at Ben Gurion University, Israel.
His research interests are in the areas of modeling pricing effects on consumer behavior at both aggregate and disaggregate
levels, product positioning, and market share forecasting and diagnostics. 相似文献
23.
Kang Byoung Uk Kim Jin-Mo Palmon Oded Zhong Zhaodong 《Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting》2020,54(4):1247-1278
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting - We examine, for various educational characteristics of hedge fund managers, the performance profile of hedge fund portfolios along their... 相似文献
24.
Jacob Oded 《Journal of Banking & Finance》2011,35(12):3174-3187
In practice, open-market stock repurchase programs outnumber self tender offers by approximately 10–1. This evidence is puzzling given that tender offers are more efficient in disbursing free cash and in signaling undervaluation – the two main motivations suggested in the literature for repurchasing shares. We provide a theoretical model to explore this puzzle. In the model, tender offers disburse free cash quickly but induce information asymmetry and hence require a price premium. Open-market programs disburse free cash slowly, and hence do not require a price premium, but because they are slow, result in partial free cash waste. The model predicts that the likelihood that a tender offer will be chosen over an open-market program increases with the agency costs of free cash and decreases with uncertainty (risk), information asymmetry, ownership concentration, and liquidity. These predictions are generally consistent with the empirical evidence. 相似文献
25.
Oded Stark Christian Helmenstein Yury Yegorov 《International Tax and Public Finance》1997,4(3):307-324
If some of the returns to migration accrue from returnmigration, the optimal duration of migration may be shorter thanthe feasible duration of migration. We develop a model that providesand highlights conditions under which return migration takesplace even though a reversal of the inter-country wage differentialdoes not occur. In particular, we consider the higher purchasingpower of savings (generated from work abroad) at home than abroadas a motive for return migration. Inter alia, our model producesa negative relationship between the optimal duration of migrationand the purchasing power differential and in some (but not all)cases, a negative relationship between the optimal duration ofmigration and the wage abroad. In addition, and contrary to ourprior anticipation, our utility maximization analysis suggeststhat East-West migration will tend to be temporary while inter-EuropeanCommunity (or intra-West European) migration will likely be permanent. 相似文献
26.
Oded Stark 《Economics Letters》2012,115(2):318-321
I study the integration of regions in the form of a merger of populations, which I interpret as a revision of people’s social space and their comparison set; I illustrate the way in which a merger can aggravate social distress; and I consider policy responses. Specifically, I view the merger of populations as a merger of income vectors; I measure social distress by aggregate relative deprivation; I demonstrate that a merger increases aggregate relative deprivation; and I show that a social planner is able to reverse this increase by means of least-cost, post-merger increases in individual incomes, but is unable to counter it by relying exclusively on a self-contained income redistribution that retains individual levels of wellbeing at their pre-merger levels. 相似文献
27.
We take issue with the reasoning of Coniglio et al. ( 2009 ) that whereas better‐skilled illegal migrants will prefer to return‐migrate, lower‐skilled illegal migrants will not. We argue that under asymmetric information, all the illegal migrants are initially paid a wage based on the average productivity of the group of illegal migrants. The better‐skilled illegal migrants thus face two “taxes:” being paid less than if they were legal, and being averaged down. Therefore, better‐skilled illegal migrants can be expected to expend more effort to become legal than lower‐skilled illegal migrants. And once legalized, there is no reason for the better‐skilled illegal migrants to want to return to their country of origin more than the lower‐skilled illegal migrants. Thus, it is the lower‐skilled illegal migrants that are likely to dominate the return migration flow. We argue that in other respects too, the model of Coniglio et al. is not based on reasonable assumptions, and that even under the postulated assumptions, the model suffers from several inconsistencies. In particular, when the rate of return to savings is an increasing function of skill level, we would expect there to be few better‐skilled individuals among illegal migrants in the first place. Also, an obvious distinction between savers and borrowers is ignored. 相似文献
28.
Environment is shifting the power balance between the organization and its members, providing the individual with the power to bargain with the organization. The present article explores the sources and consequences of this change for the individuals who are members of strategic alliances as well as for the organizations they are affiliated with. © 1995 John Wiley & Sons, Inc. 相似文献
29.
Oded Hochman 《Journal of urban economics》2011,69(1):118-135
We investigate here the agglomeration of spatial clubs in an efficient allocation of a club economy. The literature on agglomeration has focused largely on a primary agglomeration caused by direct attraction forces. We concentrate mainly on secondary and tertiary agglomerations caused by a primary agglomeration. Initially, scale economies in the provision of club goods (CGs) lead each CG to agglomerate in facilities of its club. This primary agglomeration causes a secondary concentration of population around these facilities, which in turn brings about a tertiary agglomeration of facilities of different clubs into centers in the midst of population concentration. The agglomeration of facilities occurs only if a secondary concentration of population takes place. We analyze in detail two specific patterns of agglomeration. One is the central location pattern in which the facilities of all clubs agglomerate perfectly in the middle of the complex. The second is a triple-centered complex in which the center in the middle of the complex consists of perfectly agglomerated facilities of different clubs, each with a single facility per complex. The remaining two centers also consist of facilities of different clubs, but clubs in these centers each have two facilities per complex, one in each center. Each of these two centers is located between a boundary and the middle of the complex closer to the middle of the complex than to the boundary. The facilities in these two centers form condensed clusters of facilities that may contain residential land in between the facilities. We then show that these agglomeration patterns also characterize agglomerations in general. The literature maintains that an efficiently behaving municipality increases its tax-base. This implies that it is in the municipality’s interest to achieve efficiency. The best way for a local government to achieve this desired efficiency is by partially intervening in market operations in order to internalize local externalities. Such an intervention should be limited to providing the city’s infrastructure, to taxing only residential land rents and clubs’ profits, to subsidizing the basic industry of the city, and to partially regulating land uses. Consequently, if the local governments of all complexes behave according to the above, the decentralization of the efficient allocation of the club economy would be attained. 相似文献
30.
Oded Stark 《Economics Letters》1980,5(3):235-240
Given induced rural-to-urban migration, the social cost of (unskilled) labour for urban public sector projects is shown to be lower than the formal-sector, exogenously-determined wage. This result is valid not only when the urban alternative to formal employment is unemployment but also (and more realistically) when the relevant alternatives are formal employment, informal employment and unemployment. 相似文献