全文获取类型
收费全文 | 185篇 |
免费 | 5篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 39篇 |
工业经济 | 7篇 |
计划管理 | 30篇 |
经济学 | 53篇 |
运输经济 | 2篇 |
旅游经济 | 4篇 |
贸易经济 | 28篇 |
农业经济 | 2篇 |
经济概况 | 25篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 5篇 |
2022年 | 4篇 |
2021年 | 6篇 |
2020年 | 6篇 |
2019年 | 18篇 |
2018年 | 11篇 |
2017年 | 8篇 |
2016年 | 8篇 |
2015年 | 3篇 |
2014年 | 11篇 |
2013年 | 22篇 |
2012年 | 10篇 |
2011年 | 14篇 |
2010年 | 2篇 |
2009年 | 12篇 |
2008年 | 9篇 |
2007年 | 2篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 2篇 |
2004年 | 4篇 |
2003年 | 5篇 |
2002年 | 4篇 |
2001年 | 2篇 |
2000年 | 7篇 |
1999年 | 6篇 |
1998年 | 1篇 |
1996年 | 1篇 |
1995年 | 2篇 |
1991年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有190条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
61.
Labor markets in developing economies may be afflicted by a multiplicity of interacting distortions. We consider a general equilibrium model of an economy distorted by both sector-specific sticky wages and imperfect mobility of labor. In this framework, we contrast the implications of capital accumulation in the short and long run. We show that, in contrast to both the case in the absence of a sector-specific sticky wage and the case in the absence of imperfect labor mobility, the short and long-run effects of growth on the economic system converge as the degree of labor mobility is limited. 相似文献
62.
By bridging the gap between the strategic model of sanctions and the public choice framework of sanctions, the authors introduce a new sanctions game. Contrary to an earlier finding, they show that the partial compliance of the target country, along with mild sanctions, are not only an equilibrium outcome, but also Pareto superior to non-compliance and tough economic sanctions. 相似文献
63.
Reza Oladi 《Review of International Economics》2005,13(2):205-215
A two‐country, two‐commodity model of trade is considered to reformulate the tariff retaliations. It is known that tariff retaliations lead to a Nash‐equilibrium, a non‐free‐trade outcome. However, the negotiation process underlying the Nash equilibrium does not capture the notion of retaliation properly. We use the “contingent threat situation” to reformulate tariff retaliations. In this context, we show that the free trade is a stable outcome. More surprisingly, this interesting result is also valid for the “Johnson case,” where one country is better off under the tariff‐ridden Nash equilibrium compared to free trade. 相似文献
64.
We study the response of income inequality to positive per capita oil and gas revenue shocks in Iran. Using historical data from 1973 to 2016 and vector autoregression (VAR) as well as vector error correction (VECM) model‐based impulse‐response functions, we find a positive and statistically significant response of income inequality to oil booms. We also explore possible channels through which oil booms may increase inequality, including private sector credit growth, construction investment, international trade (imports) and real economic output. We find that following an oil boom, higher imports, private sector credit growth, and real economic output can explain the increased income gap to a certain degree in Iran's oil‐based economy. Our analysis can help policymakers evaluate and accommodate the possible positive or negative effects of inequality in Iran resulting from the 2016 lifting of the embargo against the country. 相似文献
65.
Mohammad Reza Farzanegan Tim Krieger Daniel Meierrieks 《Applied economics letters》2017,24(13):893-896
We study the effect of terrorism on life satisfaction for a sample of 81 countries over the 1994–2009 period. We find that terrorism is robustly associated with less life satisfaction. This effect, however, translates into only modest social costs. 相似文献
66.
Sajjad F. Dizaji Mohammad Reza Farzanegan Alireza Naghavi 《International Tax and Public Finance》2016,23(3):522-549
This study examines how the quality of political institutions affects the distribution of the government budget in Iran. We first introduce a mechanism through which democracy can shift government expenditure from national defense (military) to productivity-enhancing public spending (e.g., education). Using impulse response functions and a variance decomposition analysis on the basis of a vector autoregressive (VAR) model, our results imply that the response of military spending to an improvement (a deterioration) of democratic institutions is negative (positive) and statistically significant, whereas that of education spending is positive (negative) and significant. Our results are robust to other indicators of political institutions, different orderings of variables in the VAR, and alternative specifications of government spending categories. 相似文献
67.
Reza C. Daniels 《Revue africaine de developpement》2008,20(1):67-93
Abstract: This paper evaluates a topic in the globalization and poverty debate that is often difficult to measure, namely the transmission of price changes associated with tariff liberalization to households. Furthermore, it raises the question of whether there are discernible differences between male‐ and female‐headed households that affect this consumption‐trade link. It is a partial analysis as a consequence, but one that demonstrates the importance of such a focus for continued research and policy development surrounding the impacts of globalization. Specifically, the paper evaluates how tariff changes impacted male‐ and female‐headed households in South Africa over the discrete periods 1995, 2000, and 2004. The analysis of consumption trends by sex of household head shows statistically significant differences which confirm that resources are managed differently between the sexes, and these are transmitted through to the tariff incidence analysis. On the whole, it was found that: (1) male‐headed households almost always bear a greater share of the tariff incidence compared to female‐headed; (2) both male‐ and female‐headed households — across all expenditure quantiles other than the most wealthy — bear a greater share of the tariff burden compared to their share of total expenditure; and (3) changes to the incidence over 1995, 2000, and 2004 between the sexes mimicked the trends for the population as a whole, but showed crucial differences at the bottom end of the expenditure distribution. This suggests that the sex of the household head matters, and must be considered in addition to other household identifying factors (e.g. socio‐economic status) when evaluating the impacts of tariff liberalization. 相似文献
68.
We formulate a model of mergers and acquisitions assuming a monopolistic competitive industry that exhibits agglomeration economies. We provide the conditions for the existence of a non‐trivial Nash equilibrium in the acquisition market at which the most productive firm acquires a range of less‐productive firms. Most importantly, we show that domestic merger and acquisition activities are international trade promotionary. We also show that such types of mergers and acquisition will improve the competitive position of foreign firms leading to an increase in their market share. In addition, domestic mergers and acquisitions will increase the number of imported varieties. 相似文献
69.
John R. Grinyer Reza Kouhy Abdussalam A. M. Elbadri 《Accounting & Business Research》2013,43(87):249-259
The concept and practical implementation of EEI has been introduced in a series of papers and has been tested for feasibility. This paper explores the reactions of managers who acted as respondents to a questionnaire in a total of seven UK and Iranian companies in which the system was tested. It discusses the limitations of the case based research methodology available, the observatons from the study and the factors that might have influenced the responses made to a questionnaire. Although EEI was generally considered to be potentially useful for some purposes, there was a marked reluctance on the part of respondents to move from established historical cost accounting practice. Some of the identified constraints on the adoption of EEI seem likely to impede the introduction of any new accounting model. 相似文献
70.
Trond Nordfjærn Amin Mohamadi Hezaveh Amir Reza Mamdoohi 《Journal of Risk Research》2013,16(5):566-580
Objective: Few studies have examined the differences in self-reported driver behaviour between drivers of one nationality who live in their country of origin (domestic drivers) and those who live abroad (expatriate drivers). This study aimed to explore the differences in self-reported driver behaviour among domestic and expatriate Iranian drivers. In addition, we explore the factors associated with self-reported accident involvement including personal injuries in these groups. Methods: A web-based version of the Driver Behaviour Questionnaire (DBQ) measuring self-reported driver errors and violations was distributed to respondents by availability sampling in social networks and by bulk email services. About 1000 individuals living in all provinces in Iran were invited to participate in the survey. We also invited Iranians living in more than 20 countries. A total of 634 domestic Iranians and 135 expatriate Iranians responded to our enquiry. The measure of driving behaviour asked the respondents about violations and error conduct during the last two years on any kind of road. The sample of domestic and expatriate drivers did not differ significantly in gender, age, education and driving hours per day. Domestic drivers were more likely to have experienced an accident in their lifetime. Both samples were relatively young of age (Domestic M integer?=?28.53, SD?=?6.85; Expatriate M integer?=?29.21, SD?=?7.71). Results: The results suggested that emotional violations were more common among the drivers living in Iran. Emotional violations and driver errors were related to self-reported accident involvement among domestic drivers while ordinary rule violations were associated with such accidents in the expatriate group. Conclusions: Iranian expatriate drivers reported less emotional violations than domestic drivers. A potential reason is that road traffic infrastructure and regulation enforcement in high-income developed countries do not facilitate emotional violations. Implications for road traffic safety and methodological limitations of the study are discussed. 相似文献