全文获取类型
收费全文 | 261篇 |
免费 | 8篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 70篇 |
工业经济 | 14篇 |
计划管理 | 59篇 |
经济学 | 82篇 |
运输经济 | 3篇 |
旅游经济 | 1篇 |
贸易经济 | 28篇 |
农业经济 | 3篇 |
经济概况 | 8篇 |
邮电经济 | 1篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2023年 | 2篇 |
2022年 | 1篇 |
2021年 | 7篇 |
2020年 | 7篇 |
2019年 | 11篇 |
2018年 | 17篇 |
2017年 | 18篇 |
2016年 | 16篇 |
2015年 | 7篇 |
2014年 | 8篇 |
2013年 | 18篇 |
2012年 | 25篇 |
2011年 | 21篇 |
2010年 | 12篇 |
2009年 | 16篇 |
2008年 | 5篇 |
2007年 | 16篇 |
2006年 | 8篇 |
2005年 | 8篇 |
2004年 | 6篇 |
2003年 | 5篇 |
2002年 | 5篇 |
2001年 | 3篇 |
2000年 | 2篇 |
1998年 | 1篇 |
1996年 | 1篇 |
1995年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 2篇 |
1993年 | 3篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 1篇 |
1983年 | 1篇 |
1980年 | 1篇 |
1978年 | 1篇 |
1974年 | 1篇 |
1972年 | 1篇 |
1970年 | 2篇 |
1969年 | 1篇 |
1968年 | 2篇 |
1967年 | 2篇 |
1966年 | 1篇 |
1964年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有269条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
1.
2.
Buyer power and supplier incentives 总被引:3,自引:0,他引:3
This paper analyzes the origins and welfare consequences of buyer power. We show that if suppliers are capacity constrained or have strictly convex costs, there are two different channels through which large buyers can obtain more favorable terms from their suppliers. In particular, we show how the presence of large buyers can then erode the value of suppliers’ outside option. Somewhat surprisingly, we show how this can induce suppliers to undertake strategies that lead to higher output and potentially higher welfare. 相似文献
3.
4.
Ferreira Petrus H. Kräussl Roman Landsman Wayne R. Borysoff Maria Nykyforovych Pope Peter F. 《Review of Accounting Studies》2019,24(4):1427-1449
Review of Accounting Studies - We directly test the reliability and relevance of investee fair values reported by listed private equity funds (LPEs). In our setting, disaggregated fair value... 相似文献
5.
Carlos Pestana Barros Shunsuke Managi Roman Matousek 《Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions & Money》2009,19(5):924-936
This paper investigates the productivity change of Japanese credit banks with a Malmquist index and the input technological bias during 2000–2006. Our results indicate that the traditional growth accounting method, which assumes Hicks neutral technological change, is not appropriate for analyzing changes in productivity. Our analysis unambiguously shows that management of Shinkin banks has to be improved. These must be based on the improvement of technical efficiency and/or technological change, emulating the procedures of the best-practice banks, i.e., those banks with Malmquist productivity scores higher than one and simultaneously with technical efficiency and technological change higher than one. 相似文献
6.
7.
Statement of the Financial Economists Roundtable: Bank Capital as a Substitute for Prudential Regulation 下载免费PDF全文
The Financial CHOICE Act recently passed by the House proposes to create an “off‐ramp” that would allow banks to escape burdensome prudential regulation if the ratio of their equity capital to their total assets is 10% or more. The Financial Economists Roundtable supports this idea as a means of reducing regulatory costs, but believes some additional safeguards are needed. A capital ratio of 10% may not be high enough to discourage banks from excessive risk taking. A solution is to have two capital requirements for banks choosing the off‐ramp: one absolute (as proposed in the act) and one risk‐based. The FER believes that many banks will prefer this regime to the current burdensome prudential regulation, especially if regulators simplify the setting of risk weights and make them more rule‐based. Regulators setting minimum capital requirements should consider not only a bank’s stand‐alone risk, but also the systemic risk posed by banks, as well as the tendency of accounting measures of income and assets to overstate the economic value of banks’ equity capital. The Financial Choice Act would also eliminate useful elements of ongoing supervision and regulation, not all of which can be addressed by higher capital alone. Furthermore, to facilitate regulatory learning about risks, off‐ramped banks should continue to report the data that regulators use for stress tests, even if they are no longer subjected to the discipline of stress tests. Finally, the act is viewed as too permissive in its treatment of off‐ramped banks that get into trouble. To prevent gaming of regulation, FERC recommends that off‐ramped banks that subsequently fall below the minimum requirements should be required to raise new capital immediately. 相似文献
8.
9.
Roman M. Sheremeta 《Journal of economic surveys》2018,32(3):683-704
Group contests are ubiquitous. Some examples include warfare between countries, competition between political parties, team‐incentives within firms, and rent‐seeking. In order to succeed, members of the same group have incentives to cooperate with each other by expending effort. However, since effort is costly, each member also has an incentive to abstain from expending any effort and instead free ride on the efforts of other members. Contest theory predicts that the intensity of competition between groups and the amount of free riding within groups depend on the group size, sharing rule, group impact function, contest success function, and heterogeneity of players. We review experimental studies testing these theoretical predictions. Most studies find significant over‐expenditure of effort relative to the theory and significant heterogeneity of behavior within and between groups. Also, most studies find support for the comparative statics predictions of the theory (with the exception of the “group size paradox”). Finally, studies show that there are effective mechanisms that can promote within‐group cooperation and conflict resolution mechanisms that can de‐escalate and potentially eliminate between‐group conflict. 相似文献
10.
Summary. This paper considers a dynamic version of Akerlof's (1970) lemons problem where buyers and sellers must engage in search
to find a trading partner. We show that if goods are durable, the market itself may provide a natural sorting mechanism. In
equilibrium, high-quality goods sell at a higher price than low-quality goods but also circulate longer. This accords with
the common wisdom that sellers who want to sell fast may have to accept a lower price. We then compare the equilibrium outcomes
under private information with those under complete information. Surprisingly, we find that for a large range of parameter
values the quilibrium outcomes under the two information regimes coincide, despite the fact that circulation time is used
to achieve separation.
Received: August 24, 2000; revised version: October 24, 2000 相似文献