全文获取类型
收费全文 | 25117篇 |
免费 | 267篇 |
国内免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 4284篇 |
工业经济 | 1485篇 |
计划管理 | 4042篇 |
经济学 | 5680篇 |
综合类 | 548篇 |
运输经济 | 87篇 |
旅游经济 | 106篇 |
贸易经济 | 6146篇 |
农业经济 | 352篇 |
经济概况 | 1982篇 |
信息产业经济 | 45篇 |
邮电经济 | 628篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 65篇 |
2022年 | 47篇 |
2021年 | 98篇 |
2020年 | 161篇 |
2019年 | 225篇 |
2018年 | 2473篇 |
2017年 | 2265篇 |
2016年 | 1475篇 |
2015年 | 316篇 |
2014年 | 390篇 |
2013年 | 1054篇 |
2012年 | 821篇 |
2011年 | 2255篇 |
2010年 | 2110篇 |
2009年 | 1880篇 |
2008年 | 1784篇 |
2007年 | 2110篇 |
2006年 | 334篇 |
2005年 | 620篇 |
2004年 | 677篇 |
2003年 | 763篇 |
2002年 | 434篇 |
2001年 | 266篇 |
2000年 | 221篇 |
1999年 | 158篇 |
1998年 | 174篇 |
1997年 | 144篇 |
1996年 | 149篇 |
1995年 | 119篇 |
1994年 | 117篇 |
1993年 | 100篇 |
1992年 | 107篇 |
1991年 | 97篇 |
1990年 | 90篇 |
1989年 | 81篇 |
1988年 | 72篇 |
1987年 | 61篇 |
1986年 | 93篇 |
1985年 | 94篇 |
1984年 | 96篇 |
1983年 | 86篇 |
1982年 | 102篇 |
1981年 | 68篇 |
1980年 | 70篇 |
1979年 | 55篇 |
1978年 | 62篇 |
1977年 | 59篇 |
1976年 | 53篇 |
1975年 | 42篇 |
1973年 | 32篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
32.
33.
Richard P. O’Neill Emily Bartholomew Fisher Benjamin F. Hobbs Ross Baldick 《Journal of Regulatory Economics》2008,34(3):220-250
The general design for the real-time electricity market presented in this paper optimizes and prices both real and reactive
power simultaneously in an AC setting, where all assets—generation, load and transmission—are allowed to bid and are financially
settled at the locational price times energy consumed or produced. The result is that transmission lines are compensated for
both capacity and admittance, providing incentives for efficient operation of transmission-related assets such as FACTS devices,
if price-taking behavior is assumed. Losses are incorporated into the design and become an operating cost for transmission.
The market design is shown to be revenue neutral and, under some assumptions, nonconfiscatory.
相似文献
34.
Cross‐listings of equities internationally are becoming more common. Using data for Europe and North America, previous studies reject the order flow diversion hypothesis, which states that international cross‐listings reduce home‐country trading volume. We test this hypothesis using data for equities cross‐listed in Singapore and Malaysia. We find that trading volume in Malaysia fell 42.9% when Singapore markets were closed for holidays. Furthermore, we show that trading volume in Malaysia did not increase following the implementation of regulations that ended the trading of Malaysian equities in Singapore in 1998. Hence, we reject the order flow diversion hypothesis. 相似文献
35.
36.
Ines Lindner 《Economic Theory》2008,35(3):607-611
We extend Condorcet’s Jury Theorem (Essai sur l’application de l’analyse à la probabilité des décisions rendues à la pluralité
des voix. De l’imprimerie royale, 1785) to weighted voting games with voters of two kinds: a fixed (possibly empty) set of
‘major’ voters with fixed weights, and an ever-increasing number of ‘minor’ voters, whose total weight is also fixed, but
where each individual’s weight becomes negligible. As our main result, we obtain the limiting probability that the jury will
arrive at the correct decision as a function of the competence of the few major players. As in Condorcet’s result the quota
q = 1/2 is found to play a prominent role.
I wish to thank Maurice Koster, Moshé Machover, Guillermo Owen and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. 相似文献
37.
Background risk can influence the performance of insurance markets that must deal with adverse selection when applicants are risk vulnerable, since they are more averse to bearing the insurable risk as a result of their exposures to background risk. We show that background risk always results in a lower deductible for the incentive constrained contract, and that a broader range of markets attains the stable sequential equilibrium cross-subsidized pair of separating contracts. We conclude that background risk always improves the performance of markets for coverage against (insurable) foreground risks that must deal with adverse selection. We also find, however, that these improvements are never sufficient to offset the cost to insureds of bearing the background risk. 相似文献
38.
39.
The Chicago Board Options Exchange concurrently listed European‐style and American‐style options on the Standard and Poor's 500 Index from April 2, 1986 through June 20, 1986. This unique time period allows for a direct measurement of the early exercise premium in American‐style index options. In this study, using ask quotes, we find average early exercise premiums ranging from 5.04 to 5.90% for calls, and from 7.97 to 10.86% for puts. Additionally, we are able to depict a potentially useful functional form of the early exercise premium. As in previous studies, we find some instances of negative early exercise premiums. However, a trading simulation shows that traders must be able to trade within the bid–ask spread to profit from these apparent arbitrage opportunities. © 2003 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 23:287–313, 2003 相似文献
40.
Terry L. Esper Thomas D. Jensen Fernanda L. Turnipseed Scot Burton 《Journal of Business Logistics》2003,24(2):177-203
The Internet has increased the level of importance of the end‐consumer market to transportation carriers. In two between subject experiments, carrier disclosure on retail merchant websites is examined as a strategic differentiation strategy. Predictions are offered concerning effects of carrier disclosure strategies on product delivery‐related expectations, consumer attitudes, and intentions to purchase a product online. Results from Study 1 reveal significant differences between disclosure and nondisclosure of the carrier for numerous product delivery‐related variables, as well as many differences between the six carriers examined in this first study. Study 2 extends these findings by showing that providing consumers with a choice of carrier leads to increased levels of satisfaction with the online experience and greater willingness to buy, relative to nondisclosure and disclosure strategies. 相似文献