首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   99篇
  免费   13篇
财政金融   27篇
工业经济   1篇
计划管理   14篇
经济学   24篇
旅游经济   3篇
贸易经济   29篇
农业经济   3篇
经济概况   10篇
邮电经济   1篇
  2023年   2篇
  2022年   2篇
  2021年   1篇
  2020年   1篇
  2018年   6篇
  2017年   8篇
  2016年   5篇
  2015年   4篇
  2014年   5篇
  2013年   22篇
  2012年   4篇
  2011年   6篇
  2010年   5篇
  2009年   8篇
  2008年   4篇
  2007年   2篇
  2006年   1篇
  2003年   3篇
  2002年   2篇
  2001年   1篇
  2000年   2篇
  1999年   1篇
  1998年   3篇
  1996年   3篇
  1995年   1篇
  1994年   1篇
  1993年   2篇
  1981年   3篇
  1975年   1篇
  1973年   2篇
  1970年   1篇
排序方式: 共有112条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
101.
102.
We consider the effects of a one-sided price regulation of one of two complementary inputs. The provider of the regulated input is a domestic firm, while the provider of the other input is a foreign firm. This describes the market structure for several digital information and communication services, where the regulated input is access while the non-regulated complementary input is content. We show that one-sided regulation may have negative welfare effects compared to a free market economy, unless the regulator has a first-mover advantage. In the latter case, regulation is welfare enhancing regardless of whether the foreign input provider uses linear or non-linear wholesale prices.  相似文献   
103.
104.
105.
If probabilities and implicit prices of elementary state-contingent claims are proportional across states, any random income stream component is valued by discounting its expectation at the riskless rate. This lacking risk adjustment is explained by degeneracy in either market risk aversion or in randomness of aggregate consumption.  相似文献   
106.
Economic integration has had ambiguous effects on industry concentration. The literature on the topic proposes various explanations for these empirical findings. This paper provides an additional theoretical argument. It shows that in a world of monopolistic competition, integration alone (modeled as a reduction of trade barriers) may exert opposing forces on industry concentration, depending on whether the barrier consists of real (frictional) or tariff costs. In particular, the Herfindahl index of industry concentration falls for a reduction in real costs, but rises for a reduction in tariff costs. The reason is that real barriers burn up resources, such that industry profitability is reduced, reducing entry, and resulting in fewer firms and a correspondingly higher concentration. Under a tariff barrier, the redistributed tariff revenue stabilizes industry profitability, resulting in more firms and a lower concentration.  相似文献   
107.
We analyze roaming policy in the market for mobile telecommunications. Firms undertake quality improving investments in network infrastructure in order to increase geographical coverage, capacity in a given area, or functionality. Prior to investments, roaming policy is determined. We show that under collusion at the investment stage, firms and a benevolent welfare maximizing regulators interests coincide, and no regulatory intervention is needed. When investments are undertaken non-cooperatively, firms and the regulators interests do not coincide. Contrary to what seems to be the regulators concern, firms would decide on a higher roaming quality than the regulator. The effects of allowing a virtual operator to enter are also examined. Furthermore, we discuss some implications for competition policy with regard to network infrastructure investment.  相似文献   
108.
In this article, we investigate scale economies in Norwegian electricity distribution companies using a quantile regression approach. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first attempt to apply this estimation technique when analysing scale economies. We estimate the cost elasticities of the two output components: network length and number of customers, to calculate returns to scale. Our results show large potential of scale economies, particularly for the smallest companies. We also find that returns to scale is increasing over time. These findings have important implications for policymakers when they are deciding the structure of the industry in the future.  相似文献   
109.
Journal of Regulatory Economics - We consider a market structure with three mobile providers, two of which are vertically integrated with nationwide coverage. The third provider (an entrant)...  相似文献   
110.
Reward systems based on balanced scorecards often connect pay to an index, that is, a weighted sum of multiple performance measures. We show that such an index contract may indeed be optimal if performance measures are nonverifiable so that the contracting parties must rely on self-enforcement. Under commonly invoked assumptions (including normally distributed measurements), we show that the weights in the index reflect a tradeoff between distortion and precision for the measures. The efficiency of the contract improves with higher precision of the index measure, because this strengthens incentives, and correlations between measurements may for this reason be beneficial. There is a caveat, however, because the index contract is not necessarily optimal for very precise measurements, although it is shown to be asymptotically optimal. We also consider hybrid measurements, and show that the principal may want to include verifiable performance measures in the relational index contract in order to improve incentives, and that this has noteworthy implications for the formal contract.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号