首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   9867篇
  免费   293篇
财政金融   1733篇
工业经济   773篇
计划管理   1740篇
经济学   2392篇
综合类   103篇
运输经济   86篇
旅游经济   154篇
贸易经济   1764篇
农业经济   468篇
经济概况   942篇
信息产业经济   1篇
邮电经济   4篇
  2023年   63篇
  2021年   84篇
  2020年   159篇
  2019年   205篇
  2018年   293篇
  2017年   319篇
  2016年   324篇
  2015年   159篇
  2014年   246篇
  2013年   1057篇
  2012年   350篇
  2011年   362篇
  2010年   284篇
  2009年   312篇
  2008年   280篇
  2007年   251篇
  2006年   228篇
  2005年   600篇
  2004年   328篇
  2003年   233篇
  2002年   182篇
  2001年   207篇
  2000年   185篇
  1999年   173篇
  1998年   156篇
  1997年   133篇
  1996年   138篇
  1995年   128篇
  1994年   110篇
  1993年   118篇
  1992年   132篇
  1991年   110篇
  1990年   113篇
  1989年   111篇
  1988年   112篇
  1987年   97篇
  1986年   116篇
  1985年   127篇
  1984年   126篇
  1983年   109篇
  1982年   117篇
  1981年   112篇
  1980年   118篇
  1979年   89篇
  1978年   111篇
  1977年   82篇
  1976年   81篇
  1975年   66篇
  1974年   57篇
  1973年   60篇
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
91.
The personal computer (PC) marketplace in the US presents a dizzying array of component suppliers and products. No single firm dominates the industry with a complete package of hardware and software components. Although one company's operating systems and general-purpose applications are installed on most PCs in the US, the other system components—processors, memory, storage devices, display adapters, monitors, specialized applications, and so on—come from any number of sources. David T. Methe, Ryoko Toyama, and Junichiro Miyabe point out that the PC industry in Japan also exhibits this decentralized nature. However, they also note that despite the decentralized network structure of the Japanese PC industry, one company—NEC—was able to achieve a dominant market share. To provide insight into the key issues involved in the management of complex technology, they contrast NEC's strategic approach to product development and organizational learning with the approaches taken by Fujitsu—the firm that placed a distant second in this market. Despite matching NEC in terms of technological capabilities, financial resources, and managerial talent, Fujitsu never managed to threaten NEC's dominance of the PC market in Japan. Fujitsu continually emphasized technological leadership, even at the expense of protecting its installed base. Poor coordination of resources and product development efforts resulted in incompatibilities among Fujitsu's various products, and the company failed to foster close relationships with suppliers of such key technologies as software and peripherals. NEC's PCs did not enjoy the advantages of first-to-market status or technological leadership. Instead, NEC achieved market dominance by finding the combination of product technologies that met the needs of the greatest number of consumers. Throughout almost 20 years of competition in the PC industry, NEC successfully maintained consistency and backward compatibility across its product lines. NEC also recognized the importance of third-party software developers, and carefully cultivated relations with these firms as a source of competitive advantage. In other words, NEC struck the right balance between three key factors: technological innovation, motivation of third-party developers of software and peripherals, and service to its installed base of customers.  相似文献   
92.
Constant Market Share (CMS) analysis is a popular tool for analyzing changes in exports of a country. Nevertheless, its theoretical foundations (and policy relevance) have been questioned. In this paper, we provide such a foundation by relating CMS analysis to a two-stage homothetic demand model. An indication of the empirical relevance of this relationship is given by comparing the CMS analysis with a two-stage Constant Elasticity of Substitution demand model applied to 1972–1976 data of the Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (ESCAP).Paper presented at the XX-th world conference of the Applied Econometric Association in Istanbul, December 1986. The research reported in this paper was carried out as part of the project Disequi-librium and Equilibrium in Demand and Supply, which is approved by the Dutch Office of Education and Sciences. Ivo J. Steyn and Philip A. ten Cate provided excellent research assistance. We thank an anonymous referee for helpful comments.  相似文献   
93.
94.
95.
Three years after launching the team-based Quality For All program, Top Chemical Company CEO Sam Verde was searching for a team-based compensation system that would reflect his company's new philosophy. With a committee gathered to discuss the issue, Verde confronts the fact that changing pay plans is an issue few people can agree on. "Very simply," explains vice president for compensation Gilbert Porterfield, "the plan is designed to give employees working on teams real incentives for constant improvement and overall excellence. The variable aspect of the system pays employees for the performance of their group." This doesn't sit well with the others. "It's going to punish teams like mine for the failings of others instead of rewarding us for the work we do and have already done," says packaging team representative Ruth Gibson. Another committee member feels that team-based anything is a "motivational happy land that doesn't square with how people really work." While Verde likes the proposed pay plan, he has doubts over whether his employees will accept the risk. Upper management has no problem basing 60% of its pay on TopChem's performance. But getting line employees to risk part of their salaries--even as little as 4%--on the ups and downs of the chemical industry may be more trouble than it's worth. Four experts on compensation reveal where Top Chemical went wrong in its plan and how Sam Verde might bring about change successfully.  相似文献   
96.
97.
Health education, risk rating and employee rebates can be combined into a comprehensive health promotion program within a benefits plan, reflecting health promotion in its truest sense.  相似文献   
98.
In summary, there are costs to maintaining separate systems to cover both work- and non-work-related injuries and illnesses; there are also significant costs associated with achieving coordination--if not integration--of the two plans. Overall, the financial data do not indicate that the overlap between workers' compensation and health benefits is of such magnitude as to justify integration regardless of cost; however, the data do suggest that judicious exploitation of opportunities to coordinate the two programs, especially in regard to managing health care providers, may generate significant savings.  相似文献   
99.
100.
The above analysis allows several conclusions to be drawn:
1)  Firstly, deregulation and liberalisation in an economy undergoing the transition from plan to market must differ somewhat from their counterparts in a highly developed market economy. This is because what is being aimed at in the transition process is to modify, not to eliminate the regulatory function of the public administration responsible for planning and implementing new institutional solutions.
2)  Secondly, privatisation of the public sector must not become a fetish, nor must it be treated as a panacea for rapid systemic changes. For objective reasons, privatisation is not susceptible to shock methods (of the cold turkey type) and therefore it is unable to rapidly induce structural changes.
3)  Thirdly, the stabilisation policy should be accompanied by a selective industrial policy carried out by the State. And the stabilisation policy must give balanced consideration to the relationship: inflation rate -output level- unempolyment rate.
  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号