首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   193篇
  免费   9篇
财政金融   65篇
工业经济   23篇
计划管理   13篇
经济学   51篇
贸易经济   14篇
农业经济   5篇
经济概况   31篇
  2020年   2篇
  2016年   4篇
  2015年   4篇
  2014年   4篇
  2013年   4篇
  2012年   4篇
  2011年   3篇
  2010年   2篇
  2009年   6篇
  2008年   6篇
  2007年   9篇
  2006年   6篇
  2005年   4篇
  2004年   2篇
  1999年   3篇
  1998年   2篇
  1997年   4篇
  1996年   5篇
  1995年   6篇
  1994年   6篇
  1993年   8篇
  1992年   8篇
  1991年   4篇
  1990年   6篇
  1989年   4篇
  1988年   4篇
  1987年   5篇
  1986年   6篇
  1985年   4篇
  1984年   3篇
  1983年   6篇
  1982年   2篇
  1980年   2篇
  1979年   2篇
  1978年   3篇
  1976年   2篇
  1975年   3篇
  1973年   3篇
  1971年   3篇
  1970年   5篇
  1969年   4篇
  1967年   3篇
  1965年   2篇
  1961年   2篇
  1958年   2篇
  1937年   2篇
  1932年   2篇
  1930年   2篇
  1929年   2篇
  1927年   1篇
排序方式: 共有202条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
181.
182.
How do workers make wage comparisons? Both an experimental study and an analysis of 16,000 British employees are reported. Satisfaction and well‐being levels are shown to depend on more than simple relative pay. They depend upon the ordinal rank of an individual's wage within a comparison group. “Rank” itself thus seems to matter to human beings. Moreover, consistent with psychological theory, quits in a workplace are correlated with pay distribution skewness.  相似文献   
183.
184.
Forward and spot exchange rates between major currencies imply large standard deviations of both predictable returns from currency speculation and of the equilibrium price measure (the intertemporal marginal rate of substitution). Representative agent theory with time-additive preferences cannot account for either of these properties. We show that the theory does considerably better along these dimensions when the representative agent's preferences exhibit habit persistence, but that the theory fails to reproduce some of the other properties of the data—in particular, the strong autocorrelation of forward premiums.  相似文献   
185.
186.
187.
Survival     
Empirical analysis of rates of return in finance implicitly condition on the security surviving into the sample. We investigate the implications of such conditioning on the time series of rates of return. In general this conditioning induces a spurious relationship between observed return and total risk for those securities that survive to be included in the sample. This result has immediate implications for the equity premium puzzle. We show how these results apply to other outstanding problems of empirical finance. Long-term autocorrelation studies focus on the statistical relation between successive holding period returns, where the holding period is of possibly extensive duration. If the equity market survives, then we find that average return in the beginning is higher than average return near the end of the time period. For this reason, statistical measures of long-term dependence are typically biased towards the rejection of a random walk. The result also has implications for event studies. There is a strong association between the magnitude of an earnings announcement and the postannouncement performance of the equity. This might be explained in part as an artefact of the stock price performance of firms in financial distress that survive an earnings announcement. The final example considers stock split studies. In this analysis we implicitly exclude securities whose price on announcement is less than the prior average stock price. We apply our results to this case, and find that the condition that the security forms part of our positive stock split sample suffices to explain the upward trend in event-related cumulated excess return in the preannouncement period.  相似文献   
188.
The concept of strategic occupations is used to explain individualistic bargaining power during the nonunion era of the U.S. steel industry. It is hypothesized that integrative technical change homogenized the wage structure, but job categories associated with strategic work resisted this pattern. The results show that the degree of wage homogenization corresponded to the degree of technical diffusion in given steel industry departments. Moreover, strategic job categories did resist the pattern of wage homogenization.  相似文献   
189.
190.
Abstract. Much work has been directed to develop aggregate efficiency measures for firms or decision-making units (DMUs) in which we are able to observe only the outputs and inputs. Assuming that each DMU has the same type of observed outputs and inputs and using only this information, Farrell's technical efficiency and the CCR ratio can be used to assign an aggregate measure of efficiency to each DMU, which can then be used to compare the efficiency of the DMUs. This paper considers a subset of the general aggregate efficiency problem called the matched output/input case in which each output is matched to exactly one input, forming a subunit. Dividing the output by the input for each subunit within a DMU yields a subunit ratio that is the output per unit input. For a particular subunit, the subunit ratios for two DMUs can be compared directly. If all the subunit ratios of one DMU exceed the corresponding subunit ratios in another DMU, then we should reasonably expect that any aggregate efficiency measure has the efficiency of the first DMU greater than the efficiency of the other DMU. This requirement is defined as the Matched Output/Input Axiom, which is then shown to be violated for certain data sets satisfying Simpson's Paradox. Both Farrell's technical efficiency and the CCR ratio are then shown to violate the Matched Output/Input Axiom, which raises questions about the overall validity of both procedures. Résumé. Les travaux visant l'élaboration de mesures globales du rendement des unités décisionnelles ou des entreprises, dans lesquelles il n'est possible d'observer que les extrants et les intrants, sont nombreux. En supposant que le même type d'extrants et d'intrants est observé pour chaque unité décisionnelle et que cette information est la seule qui soit utilisée, le rendement technique de Farrell et le ratio CCR (Charnes, Cooper et Rhodes) peuvent être utilisés pour attribuer une mesure globale de rendement à chaque unité décisionnelle, mesure qui peut ensuite permettre de comparer le rendement des différentes unités. Les auteurs étudient un sous-ensemble du problème général de rendement global, le cas de concordance extrant-intrant, dans lequel chaque extrant est associé à exactement un intrant, pour former un sous-ensemble. En divisant l'extrant par l'intrant pour chaque sous-ensemble d'une unité décisionnelle, on obtient, pour chacun d'eux, un ratio représentant l'extrant par unité d'intrant. Pour un sous-ensemble particulier, les ratios de deux unités décisionnelles peuvent faire l'objet d'une comparaison directe. Si la totalité des ratios des sous-ensembles d'une unité décisionnelle excède la totalité des ratios des sous-ensembles correspondants d'une autre unité décisionnelle, on est en droit de s'attendre à ce que l'application d'une mesure globale du rendement, quelle qu'elle soit, indique que le rendement de la première unité est supérieur à celui de la seconde. Les auteurs démontrent que ce principe, défini comme étant l'axiome de concordance extrant-intrant, est transgressé pour certains ensembles de données répondant aux critères du paradoxe de Simpson. Ils démontrent également que le rendement technique de Farrell ainsi que le ratio CCR dérogent à l'axiome de concordance extrant-intrant, ce qui les amène à s'interroger sur la validité globale des deux procédés.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号