全文获取类型
收费全文 | 23955篇 |
免费 | 39篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 4209篇 |
工业经济 | 1264篇 |
计划管理 | 3804篇 |
经济学 | 5398篇 |
综合类 | 569篇 |
运输经济 | 54篇 |
旅游经济 | 122篇 |
贸易经济 | 5685篇 |
农业经济 | 302篇 |
经济概况 | 1959篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 584篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 52篇 |
2021年 | 64篇 |
2020年 | 135篇 |
2019年 | 177篇 |
2018年 | 2438篇 |
2017年 | 2189篇 |
2016年 | 1372篇 |
2015年 | 233篇 |
2014年 | 270篇 |
2013年 | 913篇 |
2012年 | 666篇 |
2011年 | 2197篇 |
2010年 | 2034篇 |
2009年 | 1759篇 |
2008年 | 1714篇 |
2007年 | 2056篇 |
2006年 | 241篇 |
2005年 | 557篇 |
2004年 | 610篇 |
2003年 | 730篇 |
2002年 | 416篇 |
2001年 | 195篇 |
2000年 | 207篇 |
1999年 | 145篇 |
1998年 | 170篇 |
1997年 | 144篇 |
1996年 | 128篇 |
1995年 | 133篇 |
1994年 | 107篇 |
1993年 | 97篇 |
1992年 | 74篇 |
1991年 | 99篇 |
1990年 | 93篇 |
1989年 | 63篇 |
1988年 | 65篇 |
1987年 | 64篇 |
1986年 | 82篇 |
1985年 | 107篇 |
1984年 | 106篇 |
1983年 | 98篇 |
1982年 | 90篇 |
1981年 | 79篇 |
1980年 | 82篇 |
1979年 | 72篇 |
1978年 | 86篇 |
1977年 | 73篇 |
1976年 | 83篇 |
1975年 | 70篇 |
1974年 | 60篇 |
1973年 | 47篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
71.
This study examined the relationship between land inequality and human capital accumulation in the Korean colonial period by using a panel data set from 1934 to 1942. Evidence of the adverse relationship between land inequality and the accumulation of human capital has thus far only been presented by using data from Western countries and from countries that achieved industrialization not under colonial occupation but by their own economic interest. The presented findings thus contribute to the body of knowledge on this topic and confirm the generalizability of the Galor model by analyzing the unique Korean context under Japanese rule in the early twentieth century. It is the first study to present evidence that inequality in landownership had an adverse effect on the level of public education in the Korean colonial period (i.e., it is a non-financial hurdle for human capital accumulation). By using a fixed effects model and a fixed effects two-stage least squares model with an instrumental variable estimation, this study exploits variation in inequality in land concentration across regions in Korea, accounting for the unobserved heterogeneity across these regions. Overall, this analysis establishes a highly significant adverse effect of land inequality on education in the Korean colonial period. 相似文献
72.
James William Jordan 《Annals of Tourism Research》1980,7(1):34-55
A village in northern New England was the setting of fieldwork focused on the interaction between the year-round residents of the community (the natives) and their tourist season guests (the summer people). The annual round of activities is geared to the the presence and absence of the summer people; the most highly valued periods of time are the winter season when only natives are residents of the village. As the marketing of the pastoral image of their village to the summer people progresses, the natives face a dilemma. If they are sucscessful in their marketing endeavors, they will prosper financially but, at the same time, they hasten the corruption of their public ideology—the image they hold of their village. The natives are attempting to salvage their future by exploiting the summer people through a “phony-folk culture” and thereby preserving selected aspects of their traditional culture for themselves. The natives' traditional way of life becomes more and more difficult to maintain as it is distorted and consumed by the summer people. 相似文献
73.
74.
75.
The study analyses technical efficiency and efficiency change of 193 community hospitals and polyclinics across Ukraine, for
the years 1997–2001. These facilities are a subset of the medical institutions in rural Ukraine; they are identical w.r.t.
their function in the health system and share the same departmental structure. The data comprise the number of beds in the
hospitals, the number of staff employed in the hospitals as well as the polyclinics connected to the hospitals, the number
of inpatient and outpatient admissions as well as the number of surgical procedures, lab tests, X-rays performed and the number
of deaths and deaths after surgery. Because of the known sensitivity of traditional nonparametric frontier estimators to outlier
observations, we employ an order-m estimator, a robust technique, to assess the efficiency of these health care providers as well as changes of their productivity
time. The efficiency scores are calculated with an output-oriented model; they are close to unity for hospitals whereas polyclinics
seem somewhat less efficient. The Malmquist-indices averaged over all observations are close to unity indicating that productivity
does not change over during our observation period. But, depending on the period and the region, substantial deviations from
unity can be observed.
相似文献
Matthias StaatEmail: |
76.
Tetsuo Ono 《Economic Theory》2003,22(1):141-168
Summary. The purpose of this paper is to consider environmental taxation which would control emissions of firms in a model of growth
cycles. In the model presented below, the economy may experience two phases of growth and environmental quality: “the no-innovation
growth regime” and “the innovation-led growth regime”. Aggregate capital and environmental quality remain constant in the
no-innovation growth regime, while they perpetually increase in the innovation-led growth regime. The paper shows that the
tax plays a key role in determining whether the economy stably converges to one of the two regimes or fluctuates permanently
between them. It also shows that there is a critical level of the tax and that the economy obtains higher growth rates of
capital and environmental quality by raising (or reducing) the tax if the initial tax is below (or above) the critical level.
Received: April 2, 2001; revised version: March 21, 2002
RID="*"
ID="*" This research reported here was conducted within the research project “Project on Intergenerational Equity” at Institute
of Economic Research, Hitotsubashi University. I am deeply grateful to an anonymous referee for his or her insightful comments,
which greatly improved the paper. I also thank Hiroshi Honda, Yasuo Maeda, Yuji Nakayama, and participants in workshops at
Hitotsubashi University, Kyoto University, Nagoya University, Osaka University, University of Tsukuba, Yokohama National University,
and University of Tokyo for their valuable comments and suggestions. Any remaining errors are mine. 相似文献
77.
James S. Weber 《Economic Theory》2002,20(2):341-355
Summary. This paper presents a general procedure for finding profiles with the minimum number of voters required for many important
paradoxes. Borda's and Condorcet's classic examples are revisited as well as generalizations. Using Saari's procedure line,
we obtain an upper bound for the minimum number of voters needed for a profile for which the Condorcet winner is not strictly
top ranked for all weighted positional procedures. Also we give a simple upper bound on the minimum number of voters needed for a set of prescribed voting outcomes. In contrast to situations wherein small numbers of voters are needed, we consider paradoxes
requiring arbitrarily large numbers of voters as well as large numbers of alternatives. Finally we indicate connections with
statistical rank based tests.
Received: April 18, 2001; revised version: May 25, 2001 相似文献
78.
Labour economists typically assume that pay differences between occupations can be explained with variations in productivity. The empirical evidence on the validity of this assumption is surprisingly thin and subject to various potential biases. The authors use matched employer-employee panel data from Belgium for the years 1999–2006 to examine occupational productivity-wage gaps. They find that occupations play distinct roles for remuneration and productivity: while the estimations indicate a significant upward-sloping occupational wage-profile, the hypothesis of a flat productivity-profile cannot be rejected. The corresponding pattern of over- and underpayment stands up to a series of robustness tests. 相似文献
79.