全文获取类型
收费全文 | 7460篇 |
免费 | 158篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 1464篇 |
工业经济 | 652篇 |
计划管理 | 1259篇 |
经济学 | 1571篇 |
综合类 | 78篇 |
运输经济 | 38篇 |
旅游经济 | 117篇 |
贸易经济 | 1250篇 |
农业经济 | 386篇 |
经济概况 | 799篇 |
信息产业经济 | 1篇 |
邮电经济 | 3篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 53篇 |
2020年 | 95篇 |
2019年 | 123篇 |
2018年 | 158篇 |
2017年 | 161篇 |
2016年 | 173篇 |
2015年 | 88篇 |
2014年 | 166篇 |
2013年 | 763篇 |
2012年 | 234篇 |
2011年 | 270篇 |
2010年 | 208篇 |
2009年 | 239篇 |
2008年 | 204篇 |
2007年 | 201篇 |
2006年 | 175篇 |
2005年 | 185篇 |
2004年 | 153篇 |
2003年 | 161篇 |
2002年 | 146篇 |
2001年 | 178篇 |
2000年 | 164篇 |
1999年 | 155篇 |
1998年 | 133篇 |
1997年 | 122篇 |
1996年 | 130篇 |
1995年 | 123篇 |
1994年 | 102篇 |
1993年 | 122篇 |
1992年 | 128篇 |
1991年 | 108篇 |
1990年 | 113篇 |
1989年 | 108篇 |
1988年 | 116篇 |
1987年 | 94篇 |
1986年 | 113篇 |
1985年 | 124篇 |
1984年 | 119篇 |
1983年 | 110篇 |
1982年 | 111篇 |
1981年 | 112篇 |
1980年 | 111篇 |
1979年 | 90篇 |
1978年 | 112篇 |
1977年 | 79篇 |
1976年 | 75篇 |
1975年 | 61篇 |
1974年 | 53篇 |
1973年 | 52篇 |
1972年 | 42篇 |
排序方式: 共有7618条查询结果,搜索用时 11 毫秒
31.
Summary In the Netherlands not much attention is paid to money supply figures as an indicator of actual monetary conditions. This can be partly explained by the publication lag and the continuous revisions of seasonally adjusted data. However, the information that can be derived from money supply figures is limited because of temporary disturbances originating from the foreign exchange market. In this paper a correction method for these temporary disturbances is proposed. Money supply figures show a much closer link to real economic activity when corrected in this way.A different version of this essay with less emphasis on Holland but more information about other West-European countries has been published as chapter II Watching the money supply in: Eduard J. Bomhoff,Monetary Uncertainty, Amsterdam and New York, 1983. We gratefully acknowledge the able research assistance of Isolde B. Woittiez and Geert Rouwenhorst; Kempen and Co. kindly provided the two figures. 相似文献
32.
Conclusions Unlike McKenzie and Tullock, we do not know how personsshould treat their bodily organs or what is an ideal exit. That depends upon their utility goals, which are defined in output terms specific to the decision maker. We contend that the body is an input into the utility production process, and therefore, as with any input, it must be maintained and repaired at a level consistent with the output goals for maximization of utility. Thus, from this framework, it is quite consistent for a person to die with healthy organs without any thought of belief in reincarnation or the desire to bequeath one's bodily organs to others, or religious values. Self interest is all that must prevail.Also, the fact that there are interrelationships between the organs in the system, and at points these relationships take on fixed factor characteristics such that reduced levels of operation in one organ can create disorientation or coma or damage to other organs, means that the body cannot die as M-T suggest. Zero capacity for all organs at death is a technical impossibility as well as being inconsistent with the output goals of utility maximizers. 相似文献
33.
Reese TH 《Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies》1975,11(3):104-116
With a change in the Indonesian government in 1965 there came a change in government policy from pronatalist to limiting the birthrate. In January 1970 the government National Family Planning Cordinating Body was established. During the initial phase of the program family planning efforts have been limited to the islands of Java and Bali where family planning services are integrated into health service clinics. By the beginning of 1975 there were some 2400 clinics on Java and Bali. Family planning acceptors increased from 53,100 in 1969 to 1.5 million in 1974. The 1st phase of the program aimed at consolidating government support, winning local formal and informal leader support, introducing services into public clinic health systems, and building a viable administrative organization. The 2nd phase of the program has quantified the goal of the program, shifted from an emphasis on new acceptors to continuing users, broadened the participation of various government and nongovernmental groups, expanded the program into the private sector, and initiated a research and development program to stimulate local problem identification and resolution. By mid-1975 over 4.7 million women, or 34% of the married women between the ages of 15 and 44, had been recruited into the program. The East Java program has consistently been the most cost effective in terms of recruiting new acceptors. In terms of cost per couple year of protection, the trend has been steadily downward over the 3 years of study in the provinces of Jakarta, West Java, Central Java, Yogyakarta, East Java, and Bali where there are programs. The program needs to develop new approaches for those individuals who are not yet acceptors. Additionally, the program must concentrate on user continuation. 相似文献
34.
35.
36.
37.
38.
Cover and Pecorino (2005) claim that the March 1933 departure from the gold standard is the most probable break point ushering in an era of longer U.S. expansions, both absolutely and relative to subsequent recessions. Their analysis is based on cycle durations as defined by National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) reference dates. However, much of macroeconomic analysis is based on (i) growth cycles (i.e., periods when the economy's production is above or below trend) rather than absolute increases or decreases in economic activity; and (ii) aggregate time series' volatility as the prime indicator of macroeconomic stability. In light of this, we reevaluate the March 1933 break point. First, using HP‐filtered quarterly gross national product (GNP), our analysis of growth cycle durations still implies a break point near 1933. Second, we test for structural breaks in the volatility of GNP growth rates and deviations from trends. These tests suggest a structural break considerably later than 1933, perhaps as late as the 1950s. 相似文献
39.
40.