全文获取类型
收费全文 | 48601篇 |
免费 | 723篇 |
国内免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 8846篇 |
工业经济 | 3302篇 |
计划管理 | 7586篇 |
经济学 | 10758篇 |
综合类 | 881篇 |
运输经济 | 276篇 |
旅游经济 | 614篇 |
贸易经济 | 9234篇 |
农业经济 | 1747篇 |
经济概况 | 5410篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 627篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 163篇 |
2021年 | 207篇 |
2020年 | 392篇 |
2019年 | 614篇 |
2018年 | 2867篇 |
2017年 | 2665篇 |
2016年 | 1858篇 |
2015年 | 541篇 |
2014年 | 855篇 |
2013年 | 3549篇 |
2012年 | 1410篇 |
2011年 | 2908篇 |
2010年 | 2631篇 |
2009年 | 2521篇 |
2008年 | 2476篇 |
2007年 | 2656篇 |
2006年 | 929篇 |
2005年 | 1115篇 |
2004年 | 1206篇 |
2003年 | 1263篇 |
2002年 | 984篇 |
2001年 | 700篇 |
2000年 | 711篇 |
1999年 | 627篇 |
1998年 | 591篇 |
1997年 | 602篇 |
1996年 | 564篇 |
1995年 | 508篇 |
1994年 | 507篇 |
1993年 | 534篇 |
1992年 | 530篇 |
1991年 | 516篇 |
1990年 | 440篇 |
1989年 | 392篇 |
1988年 | 371篇 |
1987年 | 390篇 |
1986年 | 385篇 |
1985年 | 572篇 |
1984年 | 562篇 |
1983年 | 515篇 |
1982年 | 471篇 |
1981年 | 419篇 |
1980年 | 474篇 |
1979年 | 394篇 |
1978年 | 333篇 |
1977年 | 312篇 |
1976年 | 253篇 |
1975年 | 274篇 |
1974年 | 236篇 |
1973年 | 230篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
81.
Picking up on one of Hymer's key contributions, this paper examinesthe impact that inward foreign direct investment (FDI) intothe UK has on the patterns of development, both within and acrossregions. Using a panel of data for the manufacturing sector,the paper illustrates that even where one isolates the effecton the domestic sector alone, inward investment acts to increasethe demand for skilled, relative to unskilled labour, and alsogenerates the expected agglomeration effects in terms of thedemand for capital investment. The paper then goes on to drawcertain policy comparisons between these findings and the desiredaim of attracting FDI, notably to increase demand for labourin those regions suffering structural unemployment, and secondlyto reduce the disparities between regions. 相似文献
82.
KENNETH J. KLASSEN JEFFREY A. PITTMAN MARGARET P. REED STEVE FORTIN 《Contemporary Accounting Research》2004,21(3):639-680
We provide evidence on the impact of tax incentives and financial constraints on corporate R&D expenditure decisions. We contribute to extant research by comparing R&D expenditures in the United States and Canada, thereby exploiting the differences in the two countries' R&D tax credit mechanisms and generally accepted accounting principles. The two tax incentive mechanism designs are consistent with differing views of the degree of financial constraints faced by firms in these economies. Our sample also allows us to explore the effects of capitalizing R&D on Canadian firms. Employing a matched design, we document relations between tax credit incentives and R&D spending consistent with both Canadian and U.S. public companies responding as though they are not financially constrained. We estimate that the Canadian credit system induces, on average, $1.30 of additional R&D spending per dollar of taxes forgone while the U.S. system induces, on average, $2.96 of additional spending. We also find that firms that capitalize R&D costs in Canada spend, on average, 18 percent more on R&D. Collectively, this evidence is important to the ongoing debates in both countries concerning the appropriate design of incentives for R&D and is consistent with the assumptions found in the U.S. tax credit system, but not those found in the Canadian system. 相似文献
83.
Common sense tells us that the future is an essential element in any strategy. In addition, there is a good deal of literature on scenario planning, which is an important tool in considering the future in terms of strategy. However, in many organizations there is serious resistance to the development of scenarios, and they are not broadly implemented by companies. But even organizations that do not rely heavily on the development of scenarios do, in fact, construct visions to guide their strategies. But it might be asked, what happens when this vision is not consistent with the future? To address this problem, the present article proposes a method for checking the content and consistency of an organization's vision of the future, no matter how it was conceived. The proposed method is grounded on theoretical concepts from the field of future studies, which are described in this article. This study was motivated by the search for developing new ways of improving and using scenario techniques as a method for making strategic decisions. The method was then tested on a company in the field of information technology in order to check its operational feasibility. The test showed that the proposed method is, in fact, operationally feasible and was capable of analyzing the vision of the company being studied, indicating both its shortcomings and points of inconsistency. 相似文献
84.
A. R. Belousov 《Studies on Russian Economic Development》2008,19(5):560-561
85.
There has been growing interest within the economics discipline in the role of equity concerns in the distribution of resources. This paper presents empirical evidence from controlled laboratory experiments where third-party decision makers allocate resources between two individuals. The experimental results indicate that subjects view a wide range of different allocations as the fair distribution of resources. However, regression analysis indicates that both treatment effects and a few demographic variables explain some of this variation in fairness concepts. Most significantly, decision makers rewarded subjects who earned their favorable positions, and the gender of the decision maker was an important predictor of the allocation chosen. 相似文献
86.
This paper examines the long-run relationship between short-term and long-term interest rates (both nominal and real) in 19
countries, and explores the possibility that the relationship is statistically stable using Lc, MeanF, and SupF statistics
suggested by Hansen [1992]. Empirical results obtained from various cointegration techniques (Johansen, Phillips and Hansen,
Stock and Watson, and Park) and quarterly data (1973–1998) show considerable support for the expectations hypothesis in all
countries (except the United Kingdom). In a majority of cases, it is also found that a stable relationship exists between
the short-term and long-term interest rates. 相似文献
87.
Extant empirical research has reported nonlinear behavior within arbitrage relationships. In this article, the authors consider potential nonlinear dynamics within FTSE‐100 index and index‐futures. Such nonlinearity can be rationalized by the existence of transactions costs or through the interaction between informed and noise traders. They consider several empirical models designed to capture these alternative dynamics. Their empirical results provide evidence of a stationary basis term, and thus cointegration between index and index‐futures, and the presence of nonlinear dynamics within that relationship. The results further suggest that noise traders typically engage in momentum trading and are more prone to this behavior type when the underlying market is rising. Fundamental, or arbitrage, traders are characterized by heterogeneity, such that there is slow movement between regimes of behavior. In particular, fundamental traders act more quickly in response to small deviations from equilibrium, but are reluctant to act quickly in response to larger mispricings that are exposed to greater noise trader price risk. © 2006 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 26:343–368, 2006 相似文献
88.
We document producer price adjustment using a low‐inflation micro price dataset. On average 24% of prices adjust each month, with an average increase/decrease of 6%. Producer prices adjust more frequently than consumer prices, but their size of adjustment is typically smaller. Sectoral heterogeneity in the frequency of price adjustment is strongly related to heterogeneity in the cost structure. Fluctuations in aggregate producer price inflation occur to a large extent through variation in the relative share of upward and downward price adjustment. 相似文献
89.
Ines Lindner 《Economic Theory》2008,35(3):607-611
We extend Condorcet’s Jury Theorem (Essai sur l’application de l’analyse à la probabilité des décisions rendues à la pluralité
des voix. De l’imprimerie royale, 1785) to weighted voting games with voters of two kinds: a fixed (possibly empty) set of
‘major’ voters with fixed weights, and an ever-increasing number of ‘minor’ voters, whose total weight is also fixed, but
where each individual’s weight becomes negligible. As our main result, we obtain the limiting probability that the jury will
arrive at the correct decision as a function of the competence of the few major players. As in Condorcet’s result the quota
q = 1/2 is found to play a prominent role.
I wish to thank Maurice Koster, Moshé Machover, Guillermo Owen and two anonymous referees for helpful comments. 相似文献
90.
David Cui Andy Zhao Tracy Tian 《海外经济评论》2008,(15):30-32
外资企业离开世界工厂
据报道,2007年有224家外资企业离开了珠三角,另有29840家港资企业(占大约80000家港资企业的37.3%)也有同样的计划。另一方面,自2007年初至今,已有103家韩资企业离开了北方制造业中心山东。 相似文献