全文获取类型
收费全文 | 12049篇 |
免费 | 372篇 |
国内免费 | 1篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2316篇 |
工业经济 | 1141篇 |
计划管理 | 2154篇 |
经济学 | 2536篇 |
综合类 | 126篇 |
运输经济 | 134篇 |
旅游经济 | 219篇 |
贸易经济 | 2024篇 |
农业经济 | 616篇 |
经济概况 | 1151篇 |
邮电经济 | 5篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 75篇 |
2022年 | 50篇 |
2021年 | 112篇 |
2020年 | 212篇 |
2019年 | 306篇 |
2018年 | 319篇 |
2017年 | 322篇 |
2016年 | 318篇 |
2015年 | 234篇 |
2014年 | 337篇 |
2013年 | 1463篇 |
2012年 | 405篇 |
2011年 | 451篇 |
2010年 | 415篇 |
2009年 | 488篇 |
2008年 | 499篇 |
2007年 | 414篇 |
2006年 | 419篇 |
2005年 | 373篇 |
2004年 | 335篇 |
2003年 | 360篇 |
2002年 | 323篇 |
2001年 | 271篇 |
2000年 | 263篇 |
1999年 | 242篇 |
1998年 | 210篇 |
1997年 | 236篇 |
1996年 | 190篇 |
1995年 | 178篇 |
1994年 | 175篇 |
1993年 | 163篇 |
1992年 | 147篇 |
1991年 | 139篇 |
1990年 | 125篇 |
1989年 | 113篇 |
1988年 | 97篇 |
1987年 | 115篇 |
1986年 | 86篇 |
1985年 | 132篇 |
1984年 | 155篇 |
1983年 | 141篇 |
1982年 | 125篇 |
1981年 | 95篇 |
1980年 | 103篇 |
1979年 | 98篇 |
1978年 | 72篇 |
1977年 | 77篇 |
1976年 | 63篇 |
1974年 | 51篇 |
1973年 | 50篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 31 毫秒
31.
There has been growing interest within the economics discipline in the role of equity concerns in the distribution of resources. This paper presents empirical evidence from controlled laboratory experiments where third-party decision makers allocate resources between two individuals. The experimental results indicate that subjects view a wide range of different allocations as the fair distribution of resources. However, regression analysis indicates that both treatment effects and a few demographic variables explain some of this variation in fairness concepts. Most significantly, decision makers rewarded subjects who earned their favorable positions, and the gender of the decision maker was an important predictor of the allocation chosen. 相似文献
32.
Extant empirical research has reported nonlinear behavior within arbitrage relationships. In this article, the authors consider potential nonlinear dynamics within FTSE‐100 index and index‐futures. Such nonlinearity can be rationalized by the existence of transactions costs or through the interaction between informed and noise traders. They consider several empirical models designed to capture these alternative dynamics. Their empirical results provide evidence of a stationary basis term, and thus cointegration between index and index‐futures, and the presence of nonlinear dynamics within that relationship. The results further suggest that noise traders typically engage in momentum trading and are more prone to this behavior type when the underlying market is rising. Fundamental, or arbitrage, traders are characterized by heterogeneity, such that there is slow movement between regimes of behavior. In particular, fundamental traders act more quickly in response to small deviations from equilibrium, but are reluctant to act quickly in response to larger mispricings that are exposed to greater noise trader price risk. © 2006 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 26:343–368, 2006 相似文献
33.
34.
We investigate intraday bid‐ask spreads (BAS), volatility, and trading activity of thinly traded equity index futures contracts on the Singapore Exchange. Contrary to previous findings, we find a rather flat BAS pattern during the trading day. However, consistent with past findings, an increase in risk widens the spread and a higher trading activity reduces it. When trading occurs in a day, spreads are reduced. No significant difference in volatility between days with and without trades was detected. When trades occur, quote revisions increase, and it is positively related to the number of trades. An increase in the number of quote revisions increases the likelihood of a transaction, and when quotes are current, revisions that are accompanied by trades carry new information. We provide evidence that contracts that are thinly traded may possess liquidity attributes as long as their price quotes remain current. © 2003 Wiley Periodicals, Inc. Jrl Fut Mark 23:455–486, 2003 相似文献
35.
David Etherington 《Local Economy》1987,2(1):31-37
In this continuing discussion on the role of industrial improvement areas the author extends the arguments to suggest how IIAs could be a progressive planning tool linking economic, property and land-use strategies. 相似文献
36.
The purpose of this paper is to examine changes in stock return variances following option introduction. The sample consists of National Market System stocks and employs both transaction returns and returns based on bid and ask quotes. Variances are decomposed into portions attributable to bid-ask spreads, return autocorrelations, and intrinsic variances. Spreads play a negligible role in explaining variance changes. A generally positive component to short-term autocorrelations falls following option introduction, increasing variances over short holding periods. Intrinsic variances fall prior to the October 1987 crash, but do not change after the crash with option introduction. 相似文献
37.
Abstract: This paper examines the characteristics of firms that account for deferred tax liabilities related to government investment grants under an extended adoption timing period. Not only the recognition but also the timing decision is associated with changes in future performance and changes in the debt structure. Recognisers outperform non‐recognisers in the future, while early recognition is related to post recognition performance but only for those firms that currently perform well. Changes in the balance sheet structure are also related to both decisions. Firms with recent increases in the debt level tend to postpone recognition, while currently well‐performing firms that increase their future debt level are less likely to recognise deferred taxes. 相似文献
38.
David T. Meth Ryoko Toyama Junichiro Miyabe 《Journal of Product Innovation Management》1997,14(5):323-336
The personal computer (PC) marketplace in the US presents a dizzying array of component suppliers and products. No single firm dominates the industry with a complete package of hardware and software components. Although one company's operating systems and general-purpose applications are installed on most PCs in the US, the other system components—processors, memory, storage devices, display adapters, monitors, specialized applications, and so on—come from any number of sources. David T. Methe, Ryoko Toyama, and Junichiro Miyabe point out that the PC industry in Japan also exhibits this decentralized nature. However, they also note that despite the decentralized network structure of the Japanese PC industry, one company—NEC—was able to achieve a dominant market share. To provide insight into the key issues involved in the management of complex technology, they contrast NEC's strategic approach to product development and organizational learning with the approaches taken by Fujitsu—the firm that placed a distant second in this market. Despite matching NEC in terms of technological capabilities, financial resources, and managerial talent, Fujitsu never managed to threaten NEC's dominance of the PC market in Japan. Fujitsu continually emphasized technological leadership, even at the expense of protecting its installed base. Poor coordination of resources and product development efforts resulted in incompatibilities among Fujitsu's various products, and the company failed to foster close relationships with suppliers of such key technologies as software and peripherals. NEC's PCs did not enjoy the advantages of first-to-market status or technological leadership. Instead, NEC achieved market dominance by finding the combination of product technologies that met the needs of the greatest number of consumers. Throughout almost 20 years of competition in the PC industry, NEC successfully maintained consistency and backward compatibility across its product lines. NEC also recognized the importance of third-party software developers, and carefully cultivated relations with these firms as a source of competitive advantage. In other words, NEC struck the right balance between three key factors: technological innovation, motivation of third-party developers of software and peripherals, and service to its installed base of customers. 相似文献
39.
Peter F. Pope David A. Peel 《Journal of Business Finance & Accounting》1997,24(9&10):1433-1435
In this comment we identify the key features of the Frantz and Walker (1997) game theoretic model that drive the non-disclosure equilibrium result in their paper. We argue that, although technically correct, their model fails to capture certain aspects of real-world wage bargaining that will be important in determining optimal disclosure strategies in practice. However, Frantz and Walker's paper illustrates the potential of analytical techniques to contribute to the employee disclosure debate. 相似文献
40.