首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   114篇
  免费   6篇
财政金融   19篇
工业经济   10篇
计划管理   7篇
经济学   35篇
综合类   1篇
贸易经济   33篇
经济概况   15篇
  2022年   1篇
  2021年   2篇
  2019年   5篇
  2018年   5篇
  2017年   2篇
  2016年   4篇
  2015年   4篇
  2014年   2篇
  2013年   6篇
  2012年   8篇
  2011年   7篇
  2010年   1篇
  2009年   10篇
  2008年   6篇
  2007年   7篇
  2006年   6篇
  2005年   2篇
  2004年   6篇
  2003年   3篇
  2002年   4篇
  2001年   4篇
  2000年   2篇
  1998年   2篇
  1996年   1篇
  1995年   2篇
  1992年   1篇
  1990年   1篇
  1989年   1篇
  1986年   2篇
  1983年   1篇
  1980年   1篇
  1979年   1篇
  1977年   1篇
  1976年   2篇
  1974年   2篇
  1971年   1篇
  1970年   1篇
  1969年   1篇
  1967年   1篇
  1965年   1篇
排序方式: 共有120条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
For many decades the US dollar has remained unchallenged as the world’s dominant international currency. What is behind its persistent pre-eminence in the international monetary system and can this be expected to last? Could the euro rival or even surpass the dollar as the leading currency? If it did, what would be the consequences for Euroland?   相似文献   
32.
Before the breakup of the Bell System, U.S. telephone companies were permitted by law to ask for security deposits from a small percentage of subscribers. The companies used statistical models to decide which customers were most likely to pay their bills late and thus should be charged a deposit, but no one knew whether the models were right. So the Bell companies made a deliberate mistake. They asked for no deposit from nearly 100,000 new customers randomly selected from among those who were considered high risks. Surprisingly, quite a few paid their bills on time. As a result, the companies instituted a smarter screening strategy, which added millions to the Bell System's bottom line. Usually, individuals and organizations go to great lengths to avoid errors. Companies are designed for optimum performance rather than for learning, and mistakes are seen as defects. But as the Bell System example shows, making mistakes--correctly--is a powerful way to accelerate learning and increase competitiveness. If one of a company's fundamental assumptions is wrong, the firm can achieve success more quickly by deliberately making errors than by considering only data that support the assumption. Moreover, executives who apply a conventional, systematic approach to solving a pattern recognition problem are often slower to find a solution than those who test their assumptions by knowingly making mistakes. How do you distinguish between smart mistakes and dumb ones? The authors' consulting firm has developed, and currently uses, a five-step process for identifying constructive mistakes. In one test, the firm assumed that a mistake it was planning to make would cost a significant amount of money, but the opposite happened. By turning assumptions on their heads, the firm created more than dollar 1 million in new business.  相似文献   
33.
Gunther Tichy 《Empirica》2011,38(1):107-130
An analysis of the monetary authorities’ reports for 2005 to 2007 reveals that they were well aware of the risks of the financial crisis. They, however, tended to overemphasise the risks outside their control and to neglect those, at least partially under their control. Central banks should and could have acted already in 2005. Academic studies and their own assessments clearly indicated an accumulation of risks. Monetary authorities didn’t react as (1) they believe in self-regulating markets, and (2) in monetary instruments’ ineffectiveness to prevent bubbles, as well as (3) their tendency to assigning an extremely low probability to potential risks. This is not untypical for expert assessments: Risk assessment for complex systems is extremely complicated. If feasible at all, it would require extraordinarily complex techniques to take into account the tight coupling of system components and their complex interaction. This will not be possible in the foreseeable future. As a result reducing the system’s complexity appears to be the only way to reduce the probability and the severity of future financial crises.  相似文献   
34.
Gunther M 《Fortune》2003,147(13):98-100, 102, 104
  相似文献   
35.
The East Asian Dollar Standard, Fear of Floating, and Original Sin   总被引:26,自引:0,他引:26  
Before the crisis of 1997/98, the East Asian economies—except for Japan but including China—pegged their currencies to the US dollar. To avoid further turmoil, the IMF argues that these currencies should float more freely. However, the authors’ econometric estimations show that the dollar's predominant weight in East Asian currency baskets has returned to its pre‐crisis levels. By 2002, the day‐to‐day volatility of each country's exchange rate against the dollar had again become negligible. Most governments were rapidly accumulating a “war chest” of official dollar reserves, which portends that this exchange rate stabilization will come to extend over months or quarters. From the doctrine of “original sin” applied to emerging‐market economies, the authors argue that this fear of floating is entirely rational from the perspective of each individual country. And their joint pegging to the dollar benefits the East Asian dollar bloc as a whole, although Japan remains an important outlier.  相似文献   
36.
Because many authors have proposed stimulating the ailing Japanese economy by monetary expansion and yen depreciation, we explore the repercussions of depreciating the yen against the dollar on the other East Asian economies – which largely peg to the dollar. Since 1980, economic integration among Japan's neighbours – China, Hong Kong, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore and Thailand – has intensified and (except for China and Singapore) their business cycles have been highly synchronised. These cycles have been closely linked to fluctuations in the yen/dollar exchange rate – through changes in the export competitiveness, inflows of foreign direct investment and intra‐Asian income effects. We show that a major yen devaluation would have a negative impact on incomes in other East Asian economies and that it is not a sensible policy option for Japan.  相似文献   
37.
In the latter half of the 1980s, banking difficulties were concentrated in Texas. Because of the magnitude of these financial difficulties, interest has focused on whether an alleged inability or unwillingness of Texas banks to extend loans hampered economic growth in the state. Using various measures of banking-sector activity and economic activity in Texas over the period 1976:I-1990:IV, a structural VAR model of the Texas economy is estimated. Variance decompositions measure the interdependence of the banking and real sectors of the economy. Our results indicate a strong effect from the real sector to the financial sector. We find little evidence, though, that the deterioration observed in the Texas banking sector contributed to reduced economic growth.  相似文献   
38.
Ohne ZusammenfassungDie Besprechung beschränkt sich im wesentlichen auf die Bücher und Broschüren, die in letzter Zeit bei der Redaktion einliefen und von dieser dem Autor mit der Bitte um eine Sammelbesprechung übersandt wurden.  相似文献   
39.
40.
Summary Nowadays it is uncontested that price elasticities of demand for exports and imports are high enough to secure an improvement of the current account of the balance of payments in the case of an exchange rate devaluation. Indeed it may take some time until the effects materialize and the primary effect may even run in the opposite direction. However, doubts arise about the favourable reaction of the current account if secondary price and wage effects are taken into consideration—what has been done more thoroughly in recent times.The present study deals with the medium term aspects of exchange rate changes in Austria. In order to quantify exchange rate effects on foreign trade and prices double weighted exchange rate indices and double weighted foreign trade price indices were computed and a simple econometric model was built. Behavioural equations for quantities and prices of exports and imports (as far as possible, disaggregated for raw materials, energy and manufactures), for domestic prices and wages were estimated. In addition to this model exchange rate effects on tourism were considered separately. In order to evaluate the consequences of the revaluation of the Austrian Schilling simulations were run under the assumption that in the period 1972 till 1976 Austria had kept constant the average exchange rate of the currencies of its main trading partners (competitors). The main results are as follows: If Austria had pursued a constant exchange rate policy in terms of the export weighted exchange rate index during the years 1972 to 1976 instead of actually revaluating the Schilling by 19 percent the volume of exports would have been higher by 1 billion Schilling (at 1970 prices) whereas the volume of imports would have been lower by 16 billions Schilling; measured in current prices exports and imports would have been higher by 59 billions and 60 billions, respectively, and the receipts from tourism would have grown faster by 12 billions. Therefore, the trade balance would have deteriorated by 1 billion and the current account would have improved by 11 billions. By 1976 consumer prices and wages would have reached a higher level (+7 3/4 percent and +5 1/4 percent, respectively). The results of this study are not in contradiction to those obtained in comparable work for other countries.There is some indication pointing to a further deterioration of the current account in the longer run: The revaluation caused profit squeeze which hits exporters as well as import competing domestic producers may weaken investment and the ability to maintain market shares. The revaluation could favour the sheltered sector of the economy in comparison to the exposed sector and shift the structure of the economy to the disadvantage of the current account.  相似文献   
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号