全文获取类型
收费全文 | 48021篇 |
免费 | 177篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 8396篇 |
工业经济 | 2981篇 |
计划管理 | 8191篇 |
经济学 | 10716篇 |
综合类 | 742篇 |
运输经济 | 197篇 |
旅游经济 | 500篇 |
贸易经济 | 9067篇 |
农业经济 | 1504篇 |
经济概况 | 5241篇 |
信息产业经济 | 44篇 |
邮电经济 | 619篇 |
出版年
2021年 | 195篇 |
2020年 | 308篇 |
2019年 | 433篇 |
2018年 | 2702篇 |
2017年 | 2493篇 |
2016年 | 1712篇 |
2015年 | 522篇 |
2014年 | 727篇 |
2013年 | 2978篇 |
2012年 | 1271篇 |
2011年 | 2739篇 |
2010年 | 2479篇 |
2009年 | 2327篇 |
2008年 | 2356篇 |
2007年 | 2609篇 |
2006年 | 851篇 |
2005年 | 1097篇 |
2004年 | 1170篇 |
2003年 | 1244篇 |
2002年 | 909篇 |
2001年 | 715篇 |
2000年 | 715篇 |
1999年 | 573篇 |
1998年 | 589篇 |
1997年 | 554篇 |
1996年 | 563篇 |
1995年 | 496篇 |
1994年 | 541篇 |
1993年 | 560篇 |
1992年 | 516篇 |
1991年 | 544篇 |
1990年 | 499篇 |
1989年 | 418篇 |
1988年 | 428篇 |
1987年 | 409篇 |
1986年 | 438篇 |
1985年 | 608篇 |
1984年 | 575篇 |
1983年 | 574篇 |
1982年 | 547篇 |
1981年 | 466篇 |
1980年 | 469篇 |
1979年 | 475篇 |
1978年 | 400篇 |
1977年 | 367篇 |
1976年 | 295篇 |
1975年 | 283篇 |
1974年 | 259篇 |
1973年 | 260篇 |
1972年 | 211篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
951.
952.
The Economic Value of Water Quality 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
Stated preference values for water quality ratings based on the US Environmental Protection Agency National Water Quality
Inventory ratings provide an operational basis for benefit assessment. Iterative choice survey results for a very large, nationally
representative, Web-based panel imply an average valuation of $32 for each percent increase in lakes and rivers in the region
for which water quality is rated “Good.” Valuations are skewed, with the mean value more than double the median. Sources of
heterogeneity in benefit values include differences in responses to average water quality information and the base level of
water quality. Conjoint estimates are somewhat lower than the iterative choice values. The annual economic value of the decline
in inland US water quality from 1994 to 2000 is over $20 billion.
相似文献
953.
Kerstin Puschke 《Journal of Economics》2009,96(2):149-168
This paper shows that a firm prefers a process-based task assignment compared to a function-based one if the tasks are from functional areas which are neither too complementary nor too substitutable. We consider several projects (processes) with contributions from several functional areas. The organization can be structured along processes like product lines (M-form) or along functional areas like marketing or production (U-form). The U-form enables cost savings due to specialization or scale economies. The more effective incentives under the M-form might outweigh these savings if the functions are neither too complementary nor too substitutable. 相似文献
954.
955.
Martin Bodenstein Christopher J. Erceg Luca Guerrieri 《The Canadian journal of economics》2017,50(3):660-684
In a two‐country DSGE model, the effects of foreign demand shocks on the home country are greatly amplified if the home economy is constrained by the zero lower bound on policy interest rates. This result applies even to countries that are relatively closed to trade such as the United States. Departing from many of the existing closed‐economy models, the duration of the liquidity trap is determined endogenously. Adverse foreign shocks can extend the duration of the trap, implying more contractionary effects for the home country. The home economy is more vulnerable to adverse foreign shocks if the neutral rate is low—consistent with “secular stagnation”—and trade openness is high. 相似文献
956.
This paper uses data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY) to investigate gender differences in returns to various forms of human capital. Since the NLSY includes relatively detailed information regarding on- and off-the-job training, we place special emphasis on measuring gender differences in the incidence of and returns to formal post-school training. Also considered is the role of nonhuman capital factors such as industry and occupation in explaining the wage gap. It is found that about 60% of the gender wage gap in the sample is explained by mean differences in individual characteristics and market circumstances. This suggests a smaller role for discrimination in explaining the wage gap than previous research has found. The research indicates that training does not affect the gender wage gap. Also it is found that there is no statistically significant difference in the rate of return to other measures of human capital for women versus men. Our research suggests that the largest factors contributing to the wage gap are differences in the stocks of human capital for men and women, and differences in the distributions of men and women across industries and occupations. 相似文献
957.
958.
Stochastic dominance and Lorenz dominance are examples of orderings which require unanimous agreement among an infinite set of indices. This paper considers various subsets of inequality measures that respect Lorenz dominance, and assesses the extent to which a small number of indices can reproduce the Lorenz ordering. Using income data for 80 countries, our results suggest that Lorenz dominance can be predicted with 99% accuracy using just 3 or 4 inequality measures, as long as two of them focus on the extreme upper and lower tails of the distribution. In contrast, confining attention to the index families and parameter ranges normally considered may fail to detect the majority of occasions when Lorenz curves intersect. These results lead us to question the faith placed in procedures based on a finite set of inequality indices, and to suggest that similar lessons will apply to other types of unanimity orderings. 相似文献
959.
Raymond B. Palmquist Daniel J. Phaneuf V. Kerry Smith 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2010,46(1):19-41
Leisure activities such as local recreation trips usually take place in discrete blocks of time that are surrounded by time
devoted to other commitments. It can be costly to transfer time between blocks to allow for longer outings. These observations
affect the value of time within those blocks and suggest that traditional methods for valuing time using labor markets miss
important considerations. This paper presents a new model for time valuation that uses non-employment time commitments to
infer the shadow value of time spent in recreation. A unique survey that elicited revealed and stated preference data on household
time allocation is used to implement the model. The results support the conclusion that there is an increasing marginal value
of time for recreation as the trip length increases. 相似文献
960.
This study empirically examines the business cycle behaviour of public consumption and its main components, the public wage bill (including its breakdown into compensation per employee and public employment) and intermediate consumption, in the euro area aggregate, euro area countries and a group of selected non-euro area Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) countries (Denmark, Sweden, the UK, Japan and the US). It looks across a large number of variables and methods, using annual data from 1960 to 2005. It finds robust evidence supporting that public consumption, wages and employment co-move with the business cycle in a pro-cyclical manner with 1–2 year lags, notably for the euro area aggregate and euro area countries. The findings reflect mainly the correlation between cyclical developments, but also point to an important role of pro-cyclical discretionary fiscal policies. 相似文献