首页 | 本学科首页   官方微博 | 高级检索  
文章检索
  按 检索   检索词:      
出版年份:   被引次数:   他引次数: 提示:输入*表示无穷大
  收费全文   572篇
  免费   22篇
财政金融   90篇
工业经济   34篇
计划管理   107篇
经济学   91篇
综合类   3篇
运输经济   10篇
旅游经济   14篇
贸易经济   142篇
农业经济   40篇
经济概况   63篇
  2024年   2篇
  2023年   6篇
  2022年   5篇
  2021年   5篇
  2020年   10篇
  2019年   17篇
  2018年   21篇
  2017年   14篇
  2016年   14篇
  2015年   15篇
  2014年   21篇
  2013年   58篇
  2012年   23篇
  2011年   34篇
  2010年   24篇
  2009年   26篇
  2008年   27篇
  2007年   25篇
  2006年   23篇
  2005年   11篇
  2004年   11篇
  2003年   10篇
  2002年   8篇
  2001年   14篇
  2000年   13篇
  1999年   10篇
  1998年   17篇
  1997年   11篇
  1996年   14篇
  1995年   6篇
  1994年   10篇
  1993年   7篇
  1992年   7篇
  1991年   3篇
  1990年   4篇
  1989年   5篇
  1988年   3篇
  1987年   4篇
  1986年   4篇
  1985年   5篇
  1984年   5篇
  1983年   2篇
  1981年   3篇
  1980年   4篇
  1978年   4篇
  1977年   5篇
  1976年   5篇
  1975年   4篇
  1974年   4篇
  1970年   3篇
排序方式: 共有594条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
71.
Almost every theory of human behavior is based upon some assumption of rationalty. Such an assumption is commonly believed to be necessary in order to distinguish rational behavior, which is, from non-rational behavior, which is not amenable to scientific investigation. This article presents a thorough re-examination of this assumption, an inquiry which turns out to raise all the central issues of both the methodology and the theory of behavioral inquiry generally. It leads to the somewhat surprising conclusion that the notion of rationality does not have any meaningful role to play in behavioral inquiry, and that there is no sense in distinguishing rational from non-rational or irrational behavior. It also shows that the generalization of the utility notion in terms of information makes it into a much more powerful and subtle tool of analysis than it commonly appears to be taken for.  相似文献   
72.
Indices of total factor productivity (TFP) measure aggregate output per unit of aggregate input, providing a guide to the efficiency of agricultural production. This article outlines the relationship between production functions and TFP indices. Then, an index is constructed for South African agriculture for the period 1947‐91. The index shows that TFP grew at an average rate of 1,3 per cent per annum. However, TFP growth has increased since the reforms of the early 1980s. Since capital has been more realistically priced relative to labour, greater productivity growth has gone together with increasing employment, which must have improved social welfare.  相似文献   
73.
This article proposes a dynamic vector GARCH model for the estimation of time-varying betas. The model allows the conditional variances and the conditional covariance between individual portfolio returns and market portfolio returns to respond asymmetrically to past innovations depending on their sign. Covariances tend to be higher during market declines. There is substantial time variation in betas but the evidence on beta asymmetry is mixed. Specifically, in 50% of the cases betas are higher during market declines and for the remaining 50% the opposite is true. A time series analysis of estimated time varying betas reveals that they follow stationary mean-reverting processes. The average degree of persistence is approximately four days. It is also found that the static market model overstates non-market or, unsystematic risk by more than 10%. On the basis of an array of diagnostics it is confirmed that the vector GARCH model provides a richer framework for the analysis of the dynamics of systematic risk.  相似文献   
74.
The paper presents some estimates of the imputed dollar value of household work (HW)for Canada in 1961 and 1971, finding this to be about $16 and $38 billion respectively, equal to 40 percent of GNP. From the results we derive some implications about five questions raised in the relevant literature. First, no clear evidence of a downward trend for the ratio HW/GNP is found, contrary to U.S. results. Second, addition of HW to GNP as a welfare measure does not affect the general pattern of past growth estimates. Third, a cost–by-function method of estimating HW is found superior in its theoretical support and the detail it provides, but the opportunity-cost method, despite doubts on its theoretical validity, gives a good approximation in the aggregate, and, being simpler, is likely to remain popular. Fourth, disaggregation does matter if detail by region or family type is required, in which case data by number and ages of children and market-employment status of females are needed; for the total, a reasonable estimate (6–7 percent error)is given by further aggregated data. Fifth, sensitivity of HW to accuracy in the data used is large only for female wages chosen, in particular for the function “cooking”. Finally, though available data must be manipulated to fit the needs of HW, especially for earlier years, the extent of this is not all that much more than is commonly found for GNP estimations.  相似文献   
75.
The stability analysis of a simple linear Cournot model is extended by including two branches producing inputs to each other and for consumption. Equilibrium turns out as stable under continuous adjustment.  相似文献   
76.
77.
78.
This paper treats the problem of validating macroeconometric models. A set of nine models are estimated on the same data base and subjected to the same simulation tests. They range from the simple IS model to a relatively realistic model of the Swedish economy in the postwar period. The main conclusion is that minor specification changes may drastically alter the dynamic characteristics of models, despite the fact that the models are theoretically plausible. A second purpose of the paper is to try to bridge the gap between the simple IS or IS-LM models used in the classroom and the much larger and more complex models that are actually used.  相似文献   
79.
80.
设为首页 | 免责声明 | 关于勤云 | 加入收藏

Copyright©北京勤云科技发展有限公司  京ICP备09084417号