全文获取类型
收费全文 | 10992篇 |
免费 | 260篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 2085篇 |
工业经济 | 1033篇 |
计划管理 | 1825篇 |
经济学 | 2421篇 |
综合类 | 130篇 |
运输经济 | 118篇 |
旅游经济 | 241篇 |
贸易经济 | 1940篇 |
农业经济 | 571篇 |
经济概况 | 883篇 |
信息产业经济 | 3篇 |
邮电经济 | 2篇 |
出版年
2023年 | 55篇 |
2021年 | 49篇 |
2020年 | 128篇 |
2019年 | 170篇 |
2018年 | 182篇 |
2017年 | 220篇 |
2016年 | 218篇 |
2015年 | 150篇 |
2014年 | 224篇 |
2013年 | 1427篇 |
2012年 | 286篇 |
2011年 | 405篇 |
2010年 | 278篇 |
2009年 | 344篇 |
2008年 | 327篇 |
2007年 | 333篇 |
2006年 | 334篇 |
2005年 | 317篇 |
2004年 | 281篇 |
2003年 | 315篇 |
2002年 | 304篇 |
2001年 | 278篇 |
2000年 | 237篇 |
1999年 | 241篇 |
1998年 | 244篇 |
1997年 | 234篇 |
1996年 | 216篇 |
1995年 | 169篇 |
1994年 | 160篇 |
1993年 | 181篇 |
1992年 | 166篇 |
1991年 | 169篇 |
1990年 | 138篇 |
1989年 | 123篇 |
1988年 | 130篇 |
1987年 | 103篇 |
1986年 | 121篇 |
1985年 | 191篇 |
1984年 | 208篇 |
1983年 | 164篇 |
1982年 | 169篇 |
1981年 | 158篇 |
1980年 | 162篇 |
1979年 | 153篇 |
1978年 | 110篇 |
1977年 | 107篇 |
1976年 | 100篇 |
1975年 | 75篇 |
1974年 | 98篇 |
1973年 | 55篇 |
排序方式: 共有10000条查询结果,搜索用时 0 毫秒
131.
Using daily lottery data from Washington State by zip code from January 2011 through mid‐March 2016, we estimate that Powerball income elasticities range from ?0.16 to 0.16 as the Powerball jackpot increases from its minimum to $1.5 billion, while Mega Millions income elasticities range from ?0.08 to 0.03 as the Mega Millions jackpot increases from its minimum to $640 million. Controlling for jackpot size, each of three major game changes during this time period has a significant effect on own‐game and cross‐game sales. Despite these significant game changes, however, these lotto games are a highly regressive source of revenue for Washington State. (JEL H22, H71, L83) 相似文献
132.
Indicative bidding is a practice commonly used in sales of complex and very expensive assets. Theoretical analysis shows that efficient entry is not guaranteed under indicative bidding, since there is no equilibrium in which more qualified bidders are more likely to be selected for the final sale. Furthermore, there exist alternative bid procedures that, in theory at least, guarantee 100% efficiency and higher revenue for the seller. We employ experiments to compare actual performance between indicative bidding and one of these alternative procedures. The data shows that indicative bidding performs as well as the alternative procedure in terms of entry efficiency, while having other characteristics that favor it over the alternative procedure. Our results provide an explanation for the widespread use of indicative bidding despite the potential problem identified in the equilibrium analysis. 相似文献
133.
John Geanakoplos 《Economic Theory》2005,26(1):211-215
Summary. Arrows original proof of his impossibility theorem proceeded in two steps: showing the existence of a decisive voter, and then showing that a decisive voter is a dictator. Barbera replaced the decisive voter with the weaker notion of a pivotal voter, thereby shortening the first step, but complicating the second step. I give three brief proofs, all of which turn on replacing the decisive/pivotal voter with an extremely pivotal voter (a voter who by unilaterally changing his vote can move some alternative from the bottom of the social ranking to the top), thereby simplifying both steps in Arrows proof. My first proof is the most straightforward, and the second uses Condorcet preferences (which are transformed into each other by moving the bottom alternative to the top). The third proof proceeds by reinterpreting Step 1 of the first proof as saying that all social decisions are made the same way (neutrality).Received: 9 July 2001, Revised: 2 September 2004, JEL Classification Numbers:
D7, D70, D71.John Geanakoplos: I wish to thank Ken Arrow, Chris Avery, Don Brown, Ben Polak, Herb Scarf, Chris Shannon, Lin Zhou, and especially Eric Maskin for very helpful comments and advice. I was motivated to think of reproving Arrows theorem when I undertook to teach it to George Zettler, a mathematician friend. After I presented this paper at MIT, a graduate student there named Luis Ubeda-Rives told me he had worked out the same neutrality argument as I give in my third proof while he was in Spain nine years ago. He said he was anxious to publish on his own and not jointly, so I encourage the reader to consult his forthcoming working paper. The proofs appearing here appeared in my 1996 CFDP working paper. Proofs 2 and 3 originally used Mays notation, which I have dropped on the advice of Chris Avery. 相似文献
134.
John Smithin 《Review of Political Economy》2016,28(1):64-78
One of the main collective contributions of the various heterodox schools of monetary thought, such as circuit theory, Post Keynesian theory, modern money theory (MMT) and others, has been to stress the importance of the endogeneity of money via bank credit creation. It is necessary to stress the notion of a collective contribution because of the various claims and counter-claims to academic priority made in the literature. The recent exchange between T.I. Palley and E. Tymoigne and L.R. Wray in this journal provides a clear example of this. This response examines the differences between these writers in some detail. 相似文献
135.
Steffen Andersen Seda Ertac Uri Gneezy John A. List Sandra Maximiano 《Experimental Economics》2018,21(4):757-778
We study how culture and social structure influence bargaining behavior across gender, by exploring the negotiation culture in matrilineal and patriarchal societies using data from a laboratory experiment and a natural field experiment. One interesting result is that in both the actual marketplace and in the laboratory bargaining game, women in the matrilineal society earn more than men, at odds with years of evidence observed in the western world. We find that this result is critically driven by which side of the market the person is occupying: female (male) sellers in the matrilineal (patriarchal) society extract more of the bargaining surplus than male (female) sellers. In the buyer role, however, we observe no significant differences across societies. 相似文献
136.
Ron Goeree Julie Villeneuve Jeff Goeree John R. Penrod Lucinda Orsini Amir Abbas Tahami Monfared 《Journal of medical economics》2016,19(6):630-644
Background Lung cancer is the most common type of cancer in the world and is associated with significant mortality. Nivolumab demonstrated statistically significant improvements in progression-free survival (PFS) and overall survival (OS) for patients with advanced squamous non-small cell lung cancer (NSCLC) who were previously treated. The cost-effectiveness of nivolumab has not been assessed in Canada. A contentious component of projecting long-term cost and outcomes in cancer relates to the modeling approach adopted, with the two most common approaches being partitioned survival (PS) and Markov models. The objectives of this analysis were to estimate the cost-utility of nivolumab and to compare the results using these alternative modeling approaches.Methods Both PS and Markov models were developed using docetaxel and erlotinib as comparators. A three-health state model was used consisting of progression-free, progressed disease, and death. Disease progression and time to progression were estimated by identifying best-fitting survival curves from the clinical trial data for PFS and OS. Expected costs and health outcomes were calculated by combining health-state occupancy with medical resource use and quality-of-life assigned to each of the three health states. The health outcomes included in the model were survival and quality-adjusted-life-years (QALYs).Results Nivolumab was found to have the highest expected per-patient cost, but also improved per-patient life years (LYs) and QALYs. Nivolumab cost an additional $151,560 and $140,601 per QALY gained compared to docetaxel and erlotinib, respectively, using a PS model approach. The cost-utility estimates using a Markov model were very similar ($152,229 and $141,838, respectively, per QALY gained).Conclusions Nivolumab was found to involve a trade-off between improved patient survival and QALYs, and increased cost. It was found that the use of a PS or Markov model produced very similar estimates of expected cost, outcomes, and incremental cost-utility. 相似文献
137.
Christopher J. Coyne Russell S. Sobel John A. Dove 《The Review of Austrian Economics》2010,23(4):333-346
A large literature explores the importance of entrepreneurship as the catalyst of economic progress. In contrast, this paper
argues that entrepreneurs are the driver of economic stagnation. We analyze the non-productive entrepreneurial process and
discuss three channels through which non-productive activities have a multiplier effect culminating in economic decline and
stagnation. Drawing on examples of non-productive entrepreneurship from both underdeveloped and developed countries, we provide
insight into why economic stagnation persists in the former and why economic decline can occur in the latter. 相似文献
138.
Béla Nagy J. Doyne Farmer Jessika E. Trancik John Paul GonzalesAuthor vitae 《Technological Forecasting and Social Change》2011,78(8):1356-1364
Moore's Law has created a popular perception of exponential progress in information technology. But is the progress of IT really exponential? In this paper we examine long time series of data documenting progress in information technology gathered by [1]. We analyze six different historical trends of progress for several technologies grouped into the following three functional tasks: information storage, information transportation (bandwidth), and information transformation (speed of computation). Five of the six datasets extend back to the nineteenth century. We perform statistical analyses and show that in all six cases one can reject the exponential hypothesis at statistically significant levels. In contrast, one cannot reject the hypothesis of superexponential growth with decreasing doubling times. This raises questions about whether past trends in the improvement of information technology are sustainable. 相似文献
139.
Assessing the Degree of Spot Market Integration for U.S. Natural Gas: Evidence from Daily Price Data 总被引:1,自引:0,他引:1
This paper assesses the degree of market integration in the U.S. natural gas market following the FERC’s ‘open access’ reforms.
Daily spot prices at 76 market locations from 1993 to 1997 are used to examine the geographic extent of the market and the
speed with which market forces move prices toward equilibrium in the face of ongoing price shocks. The empirical results suggest
that the East and Central regions form a highly integrated market, but that this market is quite segmented from the more loosely
integrated Western market. 相似文献
140.
Semicommercial farms that produce multiple crops make up a largepart of the agricultural sector in developing economies. Thesefarms or agricultural households combine two fundamental unitsof microeconomic analysis: the household and the firm. Traditionaleconomic theory has dealt with these units separately. But indeveloping economies in which peasant farms dominate, theirinterdependence is of crucial importance. Researchers at theFood Research Institute, Stanford University, and at the WorldBank have developed models of agricultural households that combineproducer and consumer behavior in a theoretically consistentfashion. Recent empirical applications of these models haveextended them and expanded the range of policy issues whichcan be investigated using this general framework. This article reports the results of empirical applications ofthis model in India, Indonesia, Japan, the Republic of Korea,Malaysia, Nigeria, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Taiwan, and Thailand.It provides a comparative analysis of the policy implicationsof the approach for such matters as the welfare of farm households,the size of marketed surplus, the demand for nonagriculturalgoods and services, and for hired labor, and the availabilityof budget revenues and foreign exchange. 相似文献