全文获取类型
收费全文 | 1679篇 |
免费 | 7篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 189篇 |
工业经济 | 51篇 |
计划管理 | 360篇 |
经济学 | 544篇 |
综合类 | 5篇 |
运输经济 | 57篇 |
旅游经济 | 34篇 |
贸易经济 | 322篇 |
农业经济 | 57篇 |
经济概况 | 66篇 |
邮电经济 | 1篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 27篇 |
2023年 | 27篇 |
2022年 | 29篇 |
2021年 | 36篇 |
2020年 | 68篇 |
2019年 | 72篇 |
2018年 | 111篇 |
2017年 | 133篇 |
2016年 | 129篇 |
2015年 | 65篇 |
2014年 | 77篇 |
2013年 | 294篇 |
2012年 | 78篇 |
2011年 | 74篇 |
2010年 | 70篇 |
2009年 | 52篇 |
2008年 | 62篇 |
2007年 | 45篇 |
2006年 | 27篇 |
2005年 | 30篇 |
2004年 | 24篇 |
2003年 | 26篇 |
2002年 | 16篇 |
2001年 | 21篇 |
2000年 | 13篇 |
1999年 | 14篇 |
1998年 | 14篇 |
1997年 | 7篇 |
1996年 | 8篇 |
1995年 | 7篇 |
1994年 | 3篇 |
1993年 | 2篇 |
1992年 | 4篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
1986年 | 1篇 |
1985年 | 1篇 |
1984年 | 3篇 |
1983年 | 2篇 |
1981年 | 1篇 |
1980年 | 4篇 |
1978年 | 1篇 |
1977年 | 1篇 |
1976年 | 2篇 |
1974年 | 2篇 |
1971年 | 1篇 |
1964年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有1686条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
41.
The above analysis allows several conclusions to be drawn:
相似文献
1) | Firstly, deregulation and liberalisation in an economy undergoing the transition from plan to market must differ somewhat from their counterparts in a highly developed market economy. This is because what is being aimed at in the transition process is to modify, not to eliminate the regulatory function of the public administration responsible for planning and implementing new institutional solutions. |
2) | Secondly, privatisation of the public sector must not become a fetish, nor must it be treated as a panacea for rapid systemic changes. For objective reasons, privatisation is not susceptible to shock methods (of the cold turkey type) and therefore it is unable to rapidly induce structural changes. |
3) | Thirdly, the stabilisation policy should be accompanied by a selective industrial policy carried out by the State. And the stabilisation policy must give balanced consideration to the relationship: inflation rate -output level- unempolyment rate. |
42.
This paper applies the standard Austrian theory of capital investment to the standard interest group model of legislator behavior. Distinguishing between reputational capital and representative capital as interdependent forms of political capital, I argue that legislator behavior (specifically roll call voting) can be explained as entrepreneurial investment in political capital under uncertainty. I discuss several examples in which this approach can potentially add predictive power regarding legislative voting. 相似文献
43.
Luis Simón 《Geopolitics》2016,21(1):115-147
The winding down of military operations in Iraq and Afghanistan has prompted a scholarly debate around America’s evolving strategic role and posture in the broader Middle East. Allegedly, its isolated geographical position and “seapower” condition would allow the US to behave as an “offshore balancer”, by pulling back militarily, retreating from alliances and formal security commitments and relying on the different regional powers to balance each other. However, it remains unclear to what extent a seapower like the US would be able to effectively manipulate the balance of power in the Middle East from offshore. An examination of US strategy in the Middle East from 2009 to 2015 suggests that the main puzzle Washington confronts is not so much whether to retreat offshore or remain engaged onshore, but rather to work out the terms of onshore engagement. As this article shows, current US strategy in the Middle East revolves around the need to reconcile two seemingly contradictory sets of pressures. The first is that war fatigue, financial pressures and the ongoing reorientation of military-strategic resources towards the Asia-Pacific theatre do require that the US cuts back on its engagement elsewhere, including in the Middle East. The second relates to Washington’s deep-seated conviction that there is a direct correlation between US forward presence and the preservation of a favourable balance of power in the Middle East, which is itself critical to the security of other regions, including the Asia-Pacific. By discussing the relationship between seapower and forward presence, this article places US strategic retrenchment in the Middle East in perspective. In particular, the article transcends the rather vague notion of “balancing” and concentrates on US perceptions about which geographical areas in the Middle East need to be balanced, and how, i.e., through which alliances, instruments and policies. 相似文献
44.
Simón Sosvilla-Rivero 《Applied economics》2018,50(42):4540-4555
Expectations are at the centre of modern macroeconomic theory and policymakers. In this article, we examine the predictive ability and the consistency properties of macroeconomic expectations using data of the European Central Bank (ECB) Survey of Professional Forecasters (SPF). In particular, we provide evidence on the properties of forecasts for three key macroeconomic variables: the inflation rate, the growth rate of real gross domestic product and the unemployment rate. 相似文献
45.
Manuel Fernández López 《European Journal of the History of Economic Thought》2013,20(2):303-328
The concern for the existence of solution to the Walras - Cassel model is usually dated at the beginning of the 1930s, and one decade later the proof of existence of utility function. Ugo Broggi, however, posed both issues in 1923 and 1919, respectively, and even hinted at modern ways of solving them. He was an outstanding mathematician, a former disciple of David Hilbert and collaborator with the Giornale degli Economisti. Broggi's achievements are also linked to a critical reading of Osorio's treatise on Paretian economics. 相似文献
46.
We document the patterns of market-wide and firm-specific volatility in the Portuguese stock market over the 1991–2005 period
and test several explanations for the behavior of firm-level idiosyncratic volatility. Unlike previous studies we find no
evidence of a statistically significant rise in firm-specific volatility. On the contrary, the ratio of firm-specific risk
to total risk slightly decreases. We show that this result stems from new listings of large privatized companies that display
lower firm-specific risk. Our findings are consistent with the idea that changes in idiosyncratic volatility are related to
changes in the composition of the market.
相似文献
Ana Paula SerraEmail: |
47.
Andrés Navarro-Galera Salvador Rayo-Cantón Dionisio Buendía-Carrillo 《Applied economics》2013,45(58):6257-6276
Previous studies have highlighted the question of government loan interest as one of great current importance. Government borrowing levels are high, and reducing interest payments would generate savings to meet other spending needs and/or to lower taxation, thus supporting the sustainability of public finances. However, no previous study has presented a method for a local government to calculate its own credit risk and thus be in a position to negotiate lower interest rates on its borrowing. This article defines a financial model that enables local governments to estimate the interest rate payable on a bank loan, based on their credit risk premium, in accordance with the Basel II rules and the findings of our empirical study of large local governments. 相似文献
48.
This article adopts the “functional finance” approach to consider the utilization of expansive fiscal policies in the members of the European Monetary Union most affected by high unemployment. As they do not have their own monetary policy, fiscal deficits require the issuing of public debt without the support of the central bank. The authors consequently incorporate the notion of a (partially) balanced-budget expansion to achieve the desired stimulus in gross domestic product (GDP) with the least possible effect on public debt. Their proposal is only a sort of “imperfect” balanced-budget expansion: It is based on the idea that simultaneous increases in public revenue and expenditure can boost GDP, but without any pretension of keeping public deficit unchanged. Specifically, the authors use the case of Spain to show that a more expansive fiscal policy is desirable on economic grounds, and that only institutional constraints prevent it. They do it presenting two alternative scenarios for the coming years and analyzing their different impact on unemployment and fiscal sustainability. The first represents a firm commitment to budget consolidation, whereas the second is based on this “imperfect” application of the balanced budget multiplier. The main conclusion is that a more expansive fiscal policy is perfectly compatible with finance sustainability. 相似文献
49.
Helga Kristjánsdóttir 《Scottish journal of political economy》2010,57(5):591-614
This research looks at how foreign direct investment (FDI) in a small open economy compares with that of larger countries. I apply several specifications of the knowledge‐capital model to unique FDI data from the isolated country of Iceland, allowing for comparison with previous analysis of larger and similarly open economies. Using this together with other techniques, I seek to explain investment determinants by geography, economic size and skilled labor availability. The results of these analysis show that popular specifications do not accurately predict the effects for a small country case. 相似文献
50.
Quan Dong Juan Carlos Bárcena‐Ruiz María Begoña Garzón 《Australian economic papers》2015,54(4):250-265
We analyse why the Chinese government sets restrictions on foreign direct investment (FDI). We focus our analysis on the percentage of shares in relocated firms that the government allows to be foreign‐owned. The government's decision on this percentage depends on the entry cost, the number of firms that relocate and the weight of the consumer surplus in the objective function of the government. We show that by its choice of this percentage, the Chinese government may restrict or encourage FDI to its country. We also find that if the government may subsidise the fixed entry cost, it provides a subsidy only when the producer surplus has a greater weight than the consumer surplus in weighted welfare. In that case, the subsidy encourages relocation by both firms and permits the government to allow a lower percentage of shares to be foreign‐owned in relocated firms. 相似文献