全文获取类型
收费全文 | 4568篇 |
免费 | 22篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 578篇 |
工业经济 | 196篇 |
计划管理 | 986篇 |
经济学 | 1318篇 |
综合类 | 30篇 |
运输经济 | 106篇 |
旅游经济 | 106篇 |
贸易经济 | 923篇 |
农业经济 | 145篇 |
经济概况 | 200篇 |
邮电经济 | 2篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 54篇 |
2023年 | 71篇 |
2022年 | 53篇 |
2021年 | 74篇 |
2020年 | 141篇 |
2019年 | 173篇 |
2018年 | 265篇 |
2017年 | 331篇 |
2016年 | 233篇 |
2015年 | 135篇 |
2014年 | 189篇 |
2013年 | 758篇 |
2012年 | 213篇 |
2011年 | 205篇 |
2010年 | 211篇 |
2009年 | 154篇 |
2008年 | 147篇 |
2007年 | 123篇 |
2006年 | 106篇 |
2005年 | 107篇 |
2004年 | 85篇 |
2003年 | 59篇 |
2002年 | 68篇 |
2001年 | 49篇 |
2000年 | 50篇 |
1999年 | 36篇 |
1998年 | 35篇 |
1997年 | 26篇 |
1996年 | 27篇 |
1995年 | 18篇 |
1994年 | 15篇 |
1993年 | 28篇 |
1992年 | 12篇 |
1991年 | 22篇 |
1990年 | 11篇 |
1989年 | 17篇 |
1988年 | 12篇 |
1987年 | 22篇 |
1986年 | 17篇 |
1985年 | 18篇 |
1984年 | 19篇 |
1983年 | 20篇 |
1982年 | 17篇 |
1981年 | 16篇 |
1980年 | 11篇 |
1979年 | 11篇 |
1977年 | 15篇 |
1976年 | 9篇 |
1972年 | 11篇 |
1971年 | 10篇 |
排序方式: 共有4590条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
121.
This paper explores the impact of the adoption of inflation targeting (IT) on the dynamics of city‐level inflation in Korea using both aggregate and sector‐level data. When looking at aggregate regional inflation, we find that the mean, volatility and persistence fell in all cities in the wake of the monetary policy regime change, consistent with other evidence in the literature. Delving more deeply into the disaggregate data reveals additional insights however. For most of the changes we observe in the dynamics of regional inflation, we find that the aggregate effects are being driven primarily by sectors that fall into the ‘Services’ category. We posit that the impact of better anchored inflationary expectations is primarily on the less‐traded services sectors of the economy, where the domestic monetary policy framework has a relatively larger influence. When it comes to the increased co‐movement observed across regions under an IT regime, however, it is the ‘Commodities’ sectors rather than ‘Services’ that are responsible, probably because services inflation becomes relatively more influenced by local factors once it has stabilized within the target range. Therefore, adoption of IT may not necessarily increase all measures of regional synchronization even when the goal of better‐anchored inflationary expectations is achieved. 相似文献
122.
Isabel Pardo García 《International Advances in Economic Research》2005,11(4):459-467
The aim of this paper is to analyze the economic and social cohesion in the European Union. There are different factors to
explain the convergence process and besides, empirical findings are not conclusive. To the European Union, GDP per head interregional
differences have decreased for certain periods but it has remained unchanged or even increased for others periods. The second
report on the economic and social cohesion indicates that some decades are necessary to eliminate regional differences. These
differences in regional GDP are mainly explained by differences in their productive structures, degree of innovate activity,
communications structures, which depend on the relative level of transport infrastructures, and manpower qualifications. This
analysis allows us to obtain some conclusions to the economic policies and the social cohesion.
A preliminary version of this paper was presented in the 57th International Atlantic Conference, held in Lisbon, Portugal,
March 10–14, 2004. 相似文献
123.
Andrés Artal-Tur Juana Castillo-Giménez Carlos Llano-Verduras Francisco Requena-Silvente 《International Review of Economics & Finance》2011,20(2):157-172
The Heckscher–Ohlin–Vanek (HOV) model in its strict form has been strongly rejected by the data. Relaxing some assumptions of the standard HOV model is key to find improvements in its performance. We apply the Davis and Weinstein (2001) methodology to analyse the validity of the HOV model using regions rather than countries. Surprisingly, our results using data for 17 Spanish regions are similar to theirs with international data for OECD countries. Accounting for technological differences improves the predictive capacity of the factor proportions model and including trade costs and geography reduces significantly the missing trade problem. However, relaxing the assumption of factor price equalisation does not improve the performance of the HOV model in a regional setting. 相似文献
124.
José Ramón Cancelo Estefanía Mourelle 《International Advances in Economic Research》2005,11(2):135-147
This paper applies smooth transition models to capture the nonlinear behavior in the imports data of six major European economies and to assess whether such nonlinearities are related to business cycle asymmetries. Two classes of switch between regimes are considered: endogenously determined transition that assumes nonlinearities are generated by idiosyncratic components specific to foreign trade, and exogenous transition based on GDP growth as a more direct indicator of the cyclical state of the economy. The results support the proposition that the dynamics of imports are nonlinear. In Belgium, France, Spain, and the United Kingdom, regimes change over the business cycle, while in Germany and Italy the switch between regimes is endogenous. National characteristics play a role in defining the position of extreme regimes, the smoothness of the transition, and local dynamics within each state.Previous versions of this article have been presented at the 57th International Atlantic Economic Conference (Lisbon, Portugal, March 10–14, 2004) and at the VII Encuentro de Economía Aplicada (Vigo, Spain, June 3–5, 2004). The authors thank the conference participants and an anonymous referee for their comments. 相似文献
125.
126.
We consider a pure exchange economy with a finite set of types of agents which have incomplete and asymmetric information
on the states of nature. Our aim was to describe the equilibrium price formation and analyze how the lack of information may
affect the allocation of resources. To do so, we adapt to an asymmetric information scenario a variant of the Shapley–Shubik
game introduced by Dubey and Geanakoplos (J Math Econ 39:391–400, 2003 ). 相似文献
127.
Lenka?Fiala Sigrid?SuetensEmail authorView authors OrcID profile 《Experimental Economics》2017,20(4):755-771
We use data from experiments on finitely repeated dilemma games with fixed matching to investigate the effect of different types of information on cooperation. The data come from 71 studies using the voluntary contributions paradigm, covering 122 data points, and from 18 studies on decision-making in oligopoly, covering another 50 data points. We find similar effects in the two sets of experimental games. We find that transparency about what everyone in a group earns reduces contributions to the public good, as well as the degree of collusion in oligopoly markets. In contrast, transparency about choices tends to lead to an increase in contributions and collusion, although the size of this effect varies somewhat between the two settings. Our results are potentially useful for policy making, because they provide guidance on the type of information to target in order to stimulate or limit cooperation. 相似文献
128.
We analyze the role of the new goods margin in the Baltic countries’ exports and imports growth during the 1995–2008 period. Using the methodology developed in Kehoe and Ruhl (2013), we define the set of least-traded goods as those that account for the lowest 10% of total exports and imports in 1995, and then trace its growth in several markets including the Baltics’ main trade partners, the European Union and Russia. We find that, on average, by 2008 least-traded goods accounted for nearly 50% of total Baltic exports to their main trade partners. Moreover, we find that increases in the share of least-traded exports coincided with the timing of the trade liberalization reforms implemented by the Baltic countries. Least-traded imports also grew at robust rates, but their growth was lower than that of exports, accounting for slightly less than a quarter of total imports, that is, about half of the exports value. Moreover, we find that the shares of least-traded imports from the EU 15 and from Russia started diverging around the time the Baltic countries joined the EU, with the EU 15 share increasing and the Russian one declining. We also find that the Baltics’ share of least-traded exports outpaced that of other economies in Central and Eastern Europe. Finally, exports of new goods from the Baltic countries suffered noticeably during the Global Financial Crisis. After the crisis ended, the restart in new goods exports growth displayed mixed patterns. 相似文献
129.
Raymond B. Palmquist Daniel J. Phaneuf V. Kerry Smith 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2010,46(1):19-41
Leisure activities such as local recreation trips usually take place in discrete blocks of time that are surrounded by time
devoted to other commitments. It can be costly to transfer time between blocks to allow for longer outings. These observations
affect the value of time within those blocks and suggest that traditional methods for valuing time using labor markets miss
important considerations. This paper presents a new model for time valuation that uses non-employment time commitments to
infer the shadow value of time spent in recreation. A unique survey that elicited revealed and stated preference data on household
time allocation is used to implement the model. The results support the conclusion that there is an increasing marginal value
of time for recreation as the trip length increases. 相似文献
130.
Beatriz Junquera Jesús Ángel del Brío 《Technology Analysis & Strategic Management》2017,29(10):1139-1152
This paper aims to thoroughly look into the effects of the differences between the diverse leadership styles on innovative outputs (intensive, efficient and eco-efficient) in Spanish industrial companies. A questionnaire for the factories was sent and was received between the months of September 2013 and June 2014. A total of 142 valid questionnaires were received. Several regression models were used in the empirical analysis. The results show that charismatic leadership positively induces an intensive innovative output, at the same time as it improves firms’ eco-efficient innovative output. Likewise, the individualised consideration that characterises transformational leadership makes this leadership style produce positive results on the whole group of innovative outputs considered. At the other end of the leadership spectrum, the transactional style causes negative effects on the relationship between innovative activity and innovative outputs, and more specifically, on the efficient innovative output. 相似文献