全文获取类型
收费全文 | 85篇 |
免费 | 0篇 |
专业分类
财政金融 | 14篇 |
工业经济 | 1篇 |
计划管理 | 5篇 |
经济学 | 39篇 |
贸易经济 | 14篇 |
经济概况 | 12篇 |
出版年
2024年 | 1篇 |
2020年 | 3篇 |
2019年 | 3篇 |
2018年 | 6篇 |
2017年 | 1篇 |
2016年 | 1篇 |
2015年 | 2篇 |
2014年 | 6篇 |
2013年 | 10篇 |
2012年 | 4篇 |
2011年 | 12篇 |
2010年 | 3篇 |
2009年 | 5篇 |
2008年 | 2篇 |
2007年 | 5篇 |
2006年 | 2篇 |
2005年 | 3篇 |
2004年 | 3篇 |
2003年 | 1篇 |
2000年 | 1篇 |
1999年 | 1篇 |
1998年 | 2篇 |
1996年 | 1篇 |
1994年 | 1篇 |
1993年 | 1篇 |
1992年 | 1篇 |
1991年 | 2篇 |
1990年 | 1篇 |
1989年 | 1篇 |
排序方式: 共有85条查询结果,搜索用时 15 毫秒
31.
In this essay, we investigate the contrasting performance of Korean and Japanese stock markets before and after the East Asian currency crisis. The Korean stock markets showed a sharper decline and a faster recovery than the Japanese stock markets. First, we theoretically explain these contrasting movements of stock markets by explicitly modeling and adding some new elements to the idea of IT revolution in Greenwood and Jovanovic (Amer. Econom. Rev. 89, 1999, 116–122). Then we empirically prove that the theoretical model in this paper has some quantitative support by considering the level of monthly stock market capitalization and the return on daily stock index in Korea and Japan.JEL Classification Code: F43 相似文献
32.
Katsuhiko Nishizaki 《Research in Economics》2018,72(3):379-383
This paper studies secure implementability (Saijo et al. (2007) “Secure Implementation,” Theoretical Economics 2, pp.203–229) in linear production economies with classical preferences. Although secure implementability is in general stronger than the combination of strategy-proofness and non-bossiness (Satterthwaite and Sonnenschein (1981) “Strategy-Proof Allocation Mechanisms at Differentiable Points,” Review of Economic Studies 48, pp.587–597), this paper shows that both properties are equivalent under Pareto-efficient rules in the economies. In addition, this paper characterizes securely implementable and Pareto-efficient rules in the economies when the number of agents is two. 相似文献
33.
34.
Kenji Fujiwara 《Environmental and Resource Economics》2011,49(4):561-572
Recent empirics suggest the relevance of transport cost reductions for world trade growth along with eliminations in protectionist trade barriers. To address the welfare effects of trade cost reductions in a context of ??trade and the environment,?? we develop a two-stage game model where governments choose environmental and trade policies and firms play a Cournot-Nash game. We show that reductions in transport costs lead to lower emission taxes and higher tariffs. And, we find that the degree of pollution damage plays a central role in whether market integration is welfare-improving relative to autarky. 相似文献
35.
Constructing a model of differentiated Cournot duopoly, we consider welfare effects of trade liberalization (i.e. reductions in transport costs). We examine both multilateral trade (i.e. the firms in both countries export bilaterally) and unilateral trade, under which foreign entry is possible but the home firm cannot export. Some new results on trade gains under differentiated oligopoly are proved and their implications are discussed. 相似文献
36.
由于美国对高管薪酬的辩论愈来愈激烈,于是一些人把日本当做控制不断膨胀的薪酬的楷模.据韬睿咨询公司(Towers Perrin)统计,日本100家最大公司的首席执行官的年均收入为150万美元,而美国大型公司领导人的收入要高达1330万美元. 相似文献
37.
Kenji Kamizono Takeaki Kariya Regina Y. Liu Teruo Nakatsuma 《Asia-Pacific Financial Markets》2004,11(2):143-160
There exist several estimators for valuing the Asian option on the arithmetic mean. Among all variance reduction estimators, the one with the control variate derived from the geometric mean has been shown by Boyle et al. (1997) to perform best so far. In this paper, a new improved control variate estimator for this type of Asian option is proposed and investigated. Simulation results confirm that it does perform better than the control variate derived from the geometric mean. The improvement becomes more significant as the volatility increases and/or as the time to expiration lengthens. 相似文献
38.
39.
Kenji E. Kushida 《Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade》2011,11(3):279-307
While globally successful Japanese industries were able to use their domestic market as a springboard into international markets,
Japan’s telecommunications sector became decoupled from global markets, trapping Japanese ICT firms in the domestic market.
This persistent pattern of leading without followers was not simply the result of misguided technological choices, ill-informed corporate strategies, or insular government standard-setting
processes. Rather, the dynamics of competition, shaped and reshaped by political dynamics and regulatory structures, decoupled
it from global markets. These dynamics created a “Galapagos effect”, in which winning in an isolated domestic market led to losing in global markets. Major regulatory shifts transformed the dynamics of competition since the late 1990s, decreasing the isolation of Japan’s
telecommunications sector, but some factors pulling it along a proprietary trajectory persist. This paper highlights the dilemma
of how to develop beyond a follower status, but avoid becoming a leader without followers. 相似文献
40.
Kenji Mori 《Metroeconomica》2008,59(3):511-529
Maurice Potron was a French mathematician whose largely unknown contributions to economic analysis should be acknowledged as pioneering achievements. The purpose of this paper is to (1) reconstruct Potron's core model in terms of modern input–output analysis, (2) show that Potron proved de facto Fundamental Marxian Theorem (FMT) 48 years earlier than Morishima, Seton and Okishio by adapting the Perron–Frobenius theorems to economic problems, and (3) claim that Potron proved de facto FMT by considering heterogeneous labours 65 years earlier and even more generally than Bowles and Gintis. 相似文献